Tag Archive for: Economics

The new generation gap


Something interesting has emerged in voting patterns on both sides of the Atlantic: Young people are voting in ways that are markedly different from their elders. A great divide appears to have opened up, based not so much on income, education, or gender as on the voters’ generation.

There are good reasons for this divide. The lives of both old and young, as they are now lived, are different. Their pasts are different, and so are their prospects.

The Cold War, for example, was over even before some were born and while others were still children. Words like socialism do not convey the meaning they once did. If socialism means creating a society where shared concerns are not given short shrift—where people care about other people and the environment in which they live—so be it. Yes, there may have been failed experiments under that rubric a quarter-or half-century ago; but today’s experiments bear no resemblance to those of the past. So the failure of those past experiments says nothing about the new ones.

Older upper-middle-class Americans and Europeans have had a good life. When they entered the labour force, well-compensated jobs were waiting for them. The question they asked was what they wanted to do, not how long they would have to live with their parents before they got a job that enabled them to move out.

That generation expected to have job security, to marry young, to buy a house—perhaps a summer house, too—and finally retire with reasonable security. Overall, they expected to be better off than their parents.

While today’s older generation encountered bumps along the way, for the most part, their expectations were met. They may have made more on capital gains on their homes than from working. They almost surely found that strange, but they willingly accepted the gift of our speculative markets, and often gave themselves credit for buying in the right place at the right time.

Today, the expectations of young people, wherever they are in the income distribution, are the opposite. They face job insecurity throughout their lives. On average, many college graduates will search for months before they find a job—often only after having taken one or two unpaid internships. And they count themselves lucky, because they know that their poorer counterparts, some of whom did better in school, cannot afford to spend a year or two without income, and do not have the connections to get an internship in the first place.

Today’s young university graduates are burdened with debt—the poorer they are, the more they owe. So they do not ask what job they would like; they simply ask what job will enable them to pay their college loans, which often will burden them for 20 years or more. Likewise, buying a home is a distant dream.

These struggles mean that young people are not thinking much about retirement. If they did, they would only be frightened by how much they will need to accumulate to live a decent life (beyond bare social security), given the likely persistence of rock-bottom interest rates.

In short, today’s young people view the world through the lens of intergenerational fairness. The children of the upper middle class may do well in the end, because they will inherit wealth from their parents. While they may not like this kind of dependence, they dislike even more the alternative: a ‘fresh start’ in which the cards are stacked against their attainment of anything approaching what was once viewed as a basic middle-class lifestyle.

These inequities cannot easily be explained away. It isn’t as if these young people didn’t work hard: these hardships affect those who spent long hours studying, excelled in school, and did everything ‘right.’ The sense of social injustice—that the economic game is rigged—is enhanced as they see the bankers who brought on the financial crisis, the cause of the economy’s continuing malaise, walk away with mega-bonuses, with almost no one being held accountable for their wrongdoing. Massive fraud was committed, but somehow, no one actually perpetrated it. Political elites promised that ‘reforms’ would bring unprecedented prosperity. And they did, but only for the top 1%. Everyone else, including the young, got unprecedented insecurity.

These three realities—social injustice on an unprecedented scale, massive inequities, and a loss of trust in elites—define our political moment, and rightly so.

More of the same is not an answer. That is why the centre-left and centre-right parties in Europe are losing. America is in a strange position: while the Republican presidential candidates compete on demagoguery, with ill-thought-through proposals that would make matters worse, both of the Democratic candidates are proposing changes which—if they could only get them through Congress—would make a real difference.

Were the reforms put forward by Hillary Clinton or Bernie Sanders adopted, the financial system’s ability to prey on those already leading a precarious life would be curbed. And both have proposals for deep reforms that would change how America finances higher education.

But more needs to be done to make home ownership possible not just for those with parents who can give them a down payment, and to make retirement security possible, given the vagaries of the stock market and the near-zero-interest world we have entered. Most important, the young will not find a smooth path into the job market unless the economy is performing much better. The ‘official’ unemployment rate in the United States, at 4.9%, masks much higher levels of disguised unemployment, which, at the very least, are holding down wages.

But we won’t be able to fix the problem if we don’t recognize it. Our young do. They perceive the absence of intergenerational justice, and they are right to be angry.

Dismantling the web of harms: tackling serious and organised crime in Australia

A new report from ASPI’s Strategic Policing and Law Enforcement Program raises questions about the harms caused to Australian interests through serious and organised crime.

Those harms extend to individuals and the community, businesses and the Australian government. This claim isn’t designed to cause moral panic. Instead, we aim to reinvigorate the conversation about the harms caused by serious and organised crime to Australia’s interests, which is estimated to cost the Australian economy over $15 billion per year.

One of the more difficult questions to ask in this conversation is whether Australians actually realise the forces at work behind serious and organised crime. After all, it’s Australians’ desire for illicit commodities and services which drives demand for many organised criminal enterprises. Further organised criminal opportunities come from the increasing penetration of the cyber domain into the everyday activities of many Australians. The public’s inattention to the problem contrasts with the Australian government’s efforts to counter organised crime, which can be seen in documents such as the Crime Commission’s annual Organised Crime in Australia report and the recently-revised Organised Crime Response Plan.

Defining the web

Diagram: web of harm of serious and organised crime

Serious and organised crime poses a real national security threat in countries like Mexico or Afghanistan, where they can directly challenge government or act as an illegitimate alternative. Their problems are unlike Australia’s. But organised crime still hurts our economy, infringes on border integrity and sovereignty, damages prosperity and regional stability, and erodes political and social institutions. It also impacts upon the lives of everyday Australians and affects business costs and profits. So organised crime’s detrimental effects might be better described as a broader threat to Australia’s national interests, rather than just a threat to Australia’s national security.

We’ve identified five key harms that organised crime creates for Australia’s interests: personal and community risks for Australians, government and private revenue losses and increased costs, eroded sovereignty, safety concerns for Australian citizens and investments overseas, and political instability in some of our neighbours. We’ve used evidence gained from over 55 interviews, and drawn on research by Australian and international agencies and scholars to asse©mble a picture of these harms.

The paper concludes with a series of key questions to different groups affected by serious and organised crime. The community needs to consider whether they care about organised crime (at least enough to change our behaviour to counter it), and whether they understand where illicit goods and services, along with the criminal threat, come from. It’s also worth asking whether we know how to report instances of crime.

Businesses need to consider whether their levels of information-sharing with government on crime are optimal, if peak bodies understand the criminal threats specific to them and what the future of crime is to their industry.

Questions for government are perhaps more complex. Government should consider if there are better ways to integrate the community and businesses into an overall response to organised crime, and if there’s a better way of describing the threat to the Australian public than in terms of ‘national security’. The government needs to examine whether our current approaches to dealing with organised crime are optimal, and ask if we have the best possible system to uncover and deal with corruption. We can also enhance our international efforts to tackle the issue.

Australia hasn’t experienced the same level of violence and corruption due to serious and organised crime as other countries. But we can’t assume that’s only for a want of ambition on the part of criminals: if our law enforcement wasn’t as strong and our society not as cohesive, the harms would surely be greater. That’s why dismantling this web is in everyone’s interests.

Australia’s economic future: the challenge of reform

In the absence of significant new reforms by governments—both Federal and State—aimed at expanding opportunity and innovation, the outlook for Australia’s national income growth over the next decade is bleak.

The basis for this conclusion is simple:

  • productivity is, over time, the key determinant of national income, as per Paul Krugman’s famous dictum: in the long run, productivity isn’t everything but it’s almost everything
  • there’s good evidence in western countries, including Australia, that a secular slow-down in productivity has occurred over the last decade
  • at the same time in Australia, there’s also a strong slow-down in national income due to our declining terms of trade (the relative prices of exports to those of imports)

What this means is that for the next decade, we face a clear shift downwards in income growth, perhaps to half of the level that this economy has been used to over the past fifty years.

Contributions to growth in average incomes – stagnant labour productivity and poor national income growth (ie same growth as 2000–2012)

The improvement will still be small even if labour productivity returns to long run levels in this decade from its relatively poor growth in the 2000s. We need a productivity surge.

And there are other pressures. Depending on how rapidly baby boomers choose to retire, workforce participation—the number of us aged 15 to 64 who are employed—which is already showing signs of decline, will worsen at some point. Once established, this trend may not reverse itself, absent policy action and change in employer attitudes, for the next thirty years or so.

Of course, some of us will still prosper. There will be some income growth. But it’s likely that more of us can’t expect to enjoy rising real incomes. And the competition for a share of our slower-growing wealth could be a corrosive social issue if poorly-handled.

Alternatively, we could move to recognise this new reality and try to offset it with other policy initiatives.

Monetary policy and the actions of the Reserve Bank may not have much more scope left to offset these trends; interest rates are historically low. And fiscal policy remains beset by arguments over when to return to budget surplus.

This leaves microeconomic reform, a term which includes all manner of changes to the structure of our economy, who pays for the things we want, and which level of government offers greatest efficiency gains to delivering those things.

A generation ago, we faced a similar challenge, although the driving forces were different.

We chose to respond not by adding to the fiscal burden by borrowing, nor by over-reliance on monetary policy, but by wholesale economic reform, industry by industry, involving a comprehensive examination of both the traded and non-traded sectors of the economy.

Over more than a decade and across multiple changes of government—State as well as Federal—we pursued change and excluded no significant sector.

Economic Statements were a vehicle for change from 1987 until 1999. Because so many sectors were addressed together, each successive Statement reinforced two things:

  • change was a shared responsibility and
  • there was no escaping change, regardless of what business you might be in.

It’s my contention that this period of change altered expectations across the Australian economy.

It was no longer possible to be protected by government from the consequences of poor decision-making at the corporate level, nor was it easy to exploit market power—for union or for employer. Boards changed their approach to investment and innovation, and unions took opportunities to improve the lot of workforces by aligning better with investment plans.

Expectations are very powerful. They are, after all, a key driver of the effectiveness of monetary policy. And the famous US dictum ‘don’t fight the Fed’ indicates how powerful expectations can be.

Of course, there are many factors beyond the efforts of governments to reform that create the economy and society we have today.

But government is a crucial swing factor. It can choose to intervene, or to stand aside. If it chooses inaction, there’s an implicit signal that all will be right, eventually. And perhaps it will. Not always must government be part of the solution.

But the nature of the challenges listed above—lifting productivity, improving our terms of trade and addressing the issue of our ageing population—suggest there’s a vital role for government.

And it’s in managing Australia’s long-term economic trajectory that government has a core responsibility as well as a natural advantage—its ability to assess risks which are simply beyond the scope of other actors in our society.

We need governments to collectively choose to contribute via new policy approaches aimed squarely at real reform—in trade policy, energy policy, industrial relations, transport, planning, saving, as well as essential government-supported services like health and aged care.

These measures won’t always link directly to improved productivity and income statistics. But they offer a genuine opportunity for innovation and adaptation that’s our best chance to arrest a downward shift in Australia’s national income.

A wombat free zone in Trade

wombat As noted in my previous column on the changes the Abbott government is making to the Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, the wombat tribe has lost ownership of Trade. That’s to say, the National Party has given away or been deprived of the right to the Trade Minister job when the Coalition’s in office.

This column returns to the wombats because when an unwritten law of federal politics is repealed after nearly seven decades, it’s worthy of note. From 1956, when the Coalition was in power, the wombat tribe (the junior coalition partner Country-turned-National Party) always got Trade—and it was usually the ministry of choice for the leader of the Country/National Party. Australians became accustomed to the idea that the deputy Prime Minister would also be the Trade Minister.

The law was created by John McEwan, who held Trade for 15 years. It says much for McEwan’s impact on the culture of the wombats that his iron grip on Trade persisted as party tradition, long after McEwan’s protectionist ethos had expired. Read more

Asia Essentials: designed for and by Asians

President Suharto signing an emergency loan agreement with the International Monetary Fund, and then IMF head Michel CamdessusAsia’s hearing a great sucking sound as lots of hot money flees the region as the US Fed signals an end to the great monetary easing. India is getting jittery and Indonesia feeling some currency wobbles. East Asia faces the uneasy prospect of revisiting a series of ‘never again’ vows made during the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997–98, when the hot cash fleeing turned into a financial firestorm.

The ‘never again’ vows reflected the deep scars of the experience. But they were also part of a much broader determination that the Asian system of the 21st century will be designed for and by Asia. This is the Asia Essential which states the success or failure of Asia’s security system in the 21st century will be vital for the global system. Europe’s age recedes. Asia is rich and strong and no longer as subject to the Washington economic consensus. Read more