Tag Archive for: Economics

The death of Davos?

Now that we have entered a new period of geopolitical conflict, protectionism and regionalism, one wonders whether the cosmopolitan, globalised world of Davos is gone forever. Returning after a two-year pandemic-induced hiatus, this year’s World Economic Forum meeting in the Swiss Alps was a shadow of its former self.

In previous decades, the event was brimming with optimism. New peace agreements were forged, emerging markets were propelling themselves towards prosperity and democracy was on the march. As New York Times columnist Thomas Friedman famously put it, the world seemed increasingly ‘flat’, with all the old hurdles to international interconnectivity disappearing.

It was all somewhat hyped, as was typical of that era. Few really believed that an earthly paradise was around the corner or that history had really ended. But there was no denying that things were looking up and that Davos was the place to go to pay homage to the spirit of the time.

This year, the weather was grey and drizzly, and the talk was of war, sanctions, inflation and supply shortages. The International Monetary Fund’s managing director, Kristalina Georgieva, sought to reassure everyone that she does not expect an economic recession. But depression was the dominant mood in most of the formal and informal discussions.

Pessimism certainly seems justified. With no end in sight to Russia’s war on Ukraine, any engagement with the Russian economy or the Kremlin will remain off limits for large parts of the world—and certainly the West—for the foreseeable future. China’s trajectory, meanwhile, has become increasingly uncertain. My guess is that the country’s leadership is feeling rather uneasy about President Xi Jinping’s recent commitment to a ‘no limits’ friendship with Russia, not to mention his zero-Covid strategy, which has locked down Shanghai—China’s centre of dynamism—and exacerbated the country’s mounting economic problems.

But it’s not all doom and gloom. The fight against Covid-19 has been a triumph for science and ultimately for the idea of an open global economy. Yes, the inequities in the distribution of vaccines, treatments and tests will leave a stain on the international community’s response; but the initial wave of trade restrictions and vaccine nationalism has given way to more cooperation. The past two years have underscored the value of global scientific cooperation, open markets and well-functioning supply chains.

The pandemic offers important lessons for managing future challenges, particularly climate change. While recent developments have injected some pessimism into the climate debate, there may yet be a silver lining. Rapidly rising oil and gas prices are creating powerful incentives to accelerate the transition to renewable and alternative energy sources. If science could deliver on vaccines, it should also be able to deliver on the climate challenge. Already, there is a growing awareness that the problem warrants urgent attention.

Digitalisation has also made significant strides during the pandemic. Sweeping lockdowns gave everyone a crash course in digital tools. The technologies and processes adopted during the pandemic will transform many economic sectors for years to come. At the global level, cross-border data flows are booming and continuing to grow annually by double-digit figures.

Even surveying the bleak political landscape, one can find the occasional bright spot. For example, Finland’s and Sweden’s applications for NATO membership have renewed the alliance’s credibility and relevance, and strengthened transatlantic relations. And the European Union, having exceeded its own expectations in marshalling support for Ukraine, is now emerging as a critical pillar in the European security order. While major challenges lie ahead, the EU now has a strong foundation on which to build.

More broadly, the democratic West has regained some of its lost vigour and moral clarity in its firm, united opposition to Russia. With Russia continuing to commit the international crime of aggression (as well as numerous atrocities), its support in the United Nations General Assembly has dwindled to just a handful of outlaw regimes.

Looking ahead, the critical international issue will be how to maintain global cooperation on global challenges. Russia will be out of the picture but China will remain a key player alongside increasingly relevant countries like India. It remains to be seen what, if anything, will emerge from the ruins of the G20 this year. The creation of a new grouping with a more relevant membership would not be the worst outcome.

The old Davos glory days are certainly gone. Far from becoming flat, the world has become scattered with new trenches and barriers. But it is not all bad. The current mood of depression may be as unwarranted as was the previous ebullience. We should focus on being realistic and clear-eyed about the mounting global challenges we face. If we can manage to do that, we may yet prevail over them.

The trade-off between economic growth and wealth inequality in India

Several reports in the past few months have sounded the alarm about growing income and wealth inequality in India. The statistics cited are not wrong, but they are incomplete. And they have produced sensational, but misleading, news stories.

For example, an article based on Oxfam’s recent Inequality kills report notes: ‘India has the third-highest number of billionaires in the world.’ The story points out that India has 142 billionaires but ignores that India has 1.4 billion people. Only one in 10 million Indians is a billionaire, whereas such ‘billionaire density’ is eight in Russia, three in Brazil, more than four in China and 22 in the United States. Likewise, while ‘India has more billionaires than France, Sweden and Switzerland combined’, in terms of billionaire density, these three countries together have 18 times more billionaires than India.

It should come as no surprise that rich countries have more billionaires relative to their populations than poor countries do. For a more accurate comparison, consider billionaire density in middle-income countries. Relative to the world’s top 20 middle-income economies, India ranks quite low. Countries like Brazil, Malaysia and Thailand have a far greater number of billionaires relative to their size.

Oxfam isn’t the only organisation to point out India’s wealth gap. In December, the World inequality report 2022, the flagship publication of the World Inequality Lab at the Paris School of Economics, included India among the world’s most unequal countries. This research, coordinated by leading economists, fuelled sensational headlines—‘Poor country with affluent elite, India is going nowhere,’ or, even worse, ‘How Hindu nationalism enables India’s slide into inequality’—that turned the topic into a domestic political issue.

To be sure, inequality in both income and wealth has increased in India in recent years. According to the World inequality report, the richest 10% of Indians account for 57.1% of all income, compared with only 13.2% for the poorest half. And wealth inequality is more pronounced. The poorest half of the Indian population possesses just 5.9% of the country’s total wealth, whereas the richest 10% controls 64.7%.

But do these figures really support the claim that India is one of the world’s most unequal countries?

Although India’s poorest half holds a small percentage of the country’s total wealth, its members are still better off than their peers in most countries. Whereas India ranks 67th among the world’s 100 largest economies in terms of income earned by the poorest 50%, it ranks 17th in terms of the percentage of wealth held by the poorest half.

In any case, statistics that compare the top 10% and bottom 50%, while easy to comprehend, are not the only measures of inequality. Calculated from the World inequality report data, India’s Gini coefficient—a widely used indicator that ranges from 0, indicating perfect equality, to 1, for perfect inequality—is 0.6 for income inequality and 0.7 for wealth inequality. Compared with the largest 100 economies of the world, India lies in the middle for wealth inequality and among the top 20 for income inequality.

On balance, India is no paragon of egalitarianism, but nor is it one of the world’s most unequal countries.

A more fundamental question is whether India should continue to focus on economic growth to reduce poverty, even if it increases inequality. The answer, according to the Indian government’s 2020–21 economic survey is, unsurprisingly, an unqualified yes. The government is betting that a rising tide lifts all boats, and the facts seem to support this maxim.

In the decade from 2006 to 2016, the Indian economy averaged 7.6% annual growth—one of the fastest 10-year expansions in the country’s history. Concurrent with that growth was an increase in inequality: the share of income going to the richest 10% increased from 47.8% to 57.1%, while the share of the poorest half declined from 16.1% to 13.1%. But, over the same period, the number of people living in multidimensional poverty—a broad measure covering health, education and standard of living—decreased from 642 million to 370 million.

Although the Covid-19 pandemic reversed some of those gains, a recent working paper by the National Bureau of Economic Research shows that income inequality in India declined. Richer Indians experienced a steeper drop in income than poorer ones, as their businesses were most affected by the economic downturn. And demand for the kind of service sector jobs held by wealthier Indians fell sharply. The International Monetary Fund forecasts 24% growth for the Indian economy in the period 2021 to 2023, which one hopes will reduce both poverty and inequality.

The relationship between economic growth, poverty and inequality is complex, and the forces that influence it in richer countries may not be at play in India. Economic growth has lifted more than 250 million Indians out of poverty in a relatively short time. As a result, inequality has increased—but not to levels that should trigger alarm bells.

The new China shock

Some months ago, Chinese authorities approached some of the biggest foreign companies in the country and asked them to tap a representative to participate in a small closed-door gathering on China’s new economic strategy. The meeting was to be with a senior official at an undisclosed time and location, and, according to two people with direct knowledge of the matter who insisted on anonymity to discuss it, companies were asked to send only ethnic Chinese representatives. In both content and form, the episode captured China’s eagerness to make its economy more recognisably Chinese, developing its own technologies and energy sources while relying on domestic consumption rather than on foreign demand.

Chinese President Xi Jinping’s new strategy centres on the concept of ‘dual circulation’. Behind the technical-sounding phrase lies an idea that could change the global economic order. Instead of operating as a single economy linked to the world through trade and investment, China is fashioning itself into a bifurcated economy. One realm (‘external circulation’) will remain in contact with the rest of the world, but it will gradually be overshadowed by another one (‘internal circulation’) that will cultivate domestic demand, capital and ideas.

The purpose of dual circulation is to make China more self-reliant. After previously basing China’s development on export-led growth, policymakers are trying to diversify the country’s supply chains so that it can access technology and know-how without being bullied by the United States. In doing so, China will also seek to make other countries more dependent on it, thereby converting its external economic links into global political power.

The shift to a dual-circulation strategy raises the spectre of a new ‘China shock’ that could dwarf the impact of the first one, which struck Western economies after China’s accession to the World Trade Organization in 2001. Although China’s inclusion in the WTO generated a huge amount of wealth and lifted millions of Chinese out of poverty, it also created losers in places like the American ‘rust belt’ and the United Kingdom’s ‘red wall’ districts, setting the stage for the UK’s Brexit referendum and former US President Donald Trump’s election in 2016.

The West’s political class took a long time to wake up to the China shock, because it had committed to a strategy of ‘reciprocal engagement’, whereby Western consumers would benefit from low-cost Chinese imports and Western companies would profit from China’s economic growth by tapping its massive market. These dynamics, it was assumed, would pressure China into opening up its market and society even more. But this assumption has not been borne out.

The new China shock’s impact on the West will differ fundamentally from the first one. For starters, the dual-circulation strategy will affect different parts of the economy and society. Rather than endangering legacy industries, the goal is to dominate cutting-edge sectors and compete with legal and financial firms in the City of London, carmakers in Baden-Württemberg and biotech firms in Sweden.

Specifically, Xi’s 2015 ‘Made in China 2025’ plan emphasises sectors such as artificial intelligence, semiconductors, batteries and electric vehicles, and aims to increase the domestic content of core technological components to 40% by 2020 and 70% by 2025. The goal is to use state subsidies, export controls and controls on data to allow Chinese firms to replace foreign ones—or to make the foreign firms more Chinese. If Xi’s plan succeeds, the new China shock could hollow out as many high-paid jobs in tech and services as the first one did in heavy industry and textiles.

The shock will not end there. Today’s main geopolitical contest is not just about enforcing global rules; it is about who makes them. Whereas the West previously struggled to secure Chinese compliance with the trade, investment and intellectual property frameworks it had crafted, China is now also seeking to make and enforce the rules. There are already or have been Chinese heads at the International Telecommunication Union, the International Organization for Standardization, and the International Electrotechnical Commission, and Chinese companies are increasingly trying to define the future of technology. Huawei alone holds more than 100,000 active patents, particularly in 5G technology, where it is competing with Western companies like Ericsson and Nokia to set global standards.

Moreover, today’s competitive tensions are no longer contained within the relationship between China and the West. With its Belt and Road Initiative, China has already established a network of economic ties with more than 100 countries, and it will not hesitate to use these channels to export Chinese standards along with its model of state capitalism and state subsidies. Soon (if not already), Western companies will face the same uneven playing field in third markets as they do in China itself.

One implication of the new China shock is that the new rules on data, research and development, and standards will force prominent Western companies to acquire Chinese characteristics, unless they withdraw from China altogether. As one well-placed private-sector observer put it to me, ‘China’s idea is that if companies like Daimler or Volkswagen want to work in China, they will have to move services, R&D, and new products there. Beijing hopes that dual circulation will transform them into Chinese companies.’

Needless to say, the new China shock demands a different set of responses than the old one did. Rather than trying to transform China or make inroads into the Chinese market, the West’s priority must be to transform itself, not least by developing industrial and investment policies to spur innovation and protect its intellectual property. And to ensure that their economic ‘champions’ have access to economies of scale, Western countries must establish shared standards for privacy, data protection, carbon pricing and other issues. Ideally, this cooperation would formalise new trade agreements, investment packages, financing and regulations to expand the share of the global economy that is open to non-Chinese technologies and frameworks.

Europeans, for their part, will need to enact domestic reforms to protect themselves from economic coercion in a world of gated globalisation and weaponised interdependence. While much of the attention now is on China’s crackdown in Hong Kong and repression of the Uyghur minority in Xinjiang, there is an even bigger shockwave approaching. Western leaders must not be caught off balance again.

The end of Australia’s China boom shouldn’t be such a surprise

Australian lobster, wine, beef, barley, cotton and copper ore sales to Chinese consumers and companies are being stopped by the Chinese government. What’s happening is not just a transitory interruption, regardless of whether the blanket bans foreshadowed last week are about to emerge or stay blurry.

Last week’s threats are simply the most recent and clearest indication that the temporary but highly profitable China market boom for Australia’s commodity and services exports that has run since 2014 is ending—and probably pretty quickly.

That’s what booms do, and it’s never a happy time as the painful realisation emerges.

We’ve been here before, and the psychology and political analysis aren’t that different. During the 2000s into the 2010s, we welcomed the cash flowing from the mining and mining investment booms. We had warnings from bodies like the International Monetary Fund about the economic risks that made those income streams vulnerable, but we told ourselves it was the new normal. As the Australian National University’s Warwick McKibbin said, ‘All politicians and certainly a lot of public servants seemed to believe that this boom would go forever.’ But it didn’t.

There were suggestions that Australia wasn’t taking advantage of the fat times from the boom to make provision for the future. Ideas were floated like starting a sovereign wealth fund with the government revenue received from the big miners, as Norway had done so successfully from its oil and gas revenues. But Treasury discounted these suggestions. Nevertheless, the investment boom ended, as we all knew it would.

The lazy expectation of inexorable increases in Australia’s trade with China was best expressed in the Gillard government’s forgettable Australia in the Asian century white paper from 2012.The document now seems quaint or maybe naive in its failure to acknowledge that state power, strategic interests and security issues can and will shape trade and economics. It was in good company, though. Treasury reports from the same time projected ‘increasing demand for Australian exports in the services sector and in high-end food, beverages and leisure from the increasing size of the middle class in China, as incomes rise’. Again, this economic portfolio analysis failed to acknowledge strategic, geopolitical and security risks to such rosy projections.

So, what’s going on? The way we talk about Australia’s China trade is as if the current volume and structure of that trade is, and always has been, a part of our economic furniture. It’s as if we have always sold 90% of our lobster exports to China every year, and as if we’ve always sold $1.2 billion of alcoholic drinks, $1.5 billion in timber and woodchips and $2.7 billion of beef into the China market every year, forever.

But that’s simply not true, as detailed trade data released by the government earlier this year, and analysed by David Uren, shows. Every commodity listed there has had the most extraordinary boom in sales into China since 2014. Annual lobster exports to China went from almost zero in 2014 to $800 million last year. Beef sales into China grew by 300% over the past five years. Alcoholic drink exports, dominated by wine, went from $210 million a year in 2014 to $1.2 billion in 2019. This phenomenon was powered by the 2015 free trade agreement. But growth rates of 300% and 500% are supernormal, and in economics, supernormal growth is usually temporary and often followed by a nasty slump.

Why is the China market boom ending? Because China has changed under Xi Jinping, and Xi has changed the terms under which companies and countries can access the China market. He’s also changed the terms on which Chinese businesses can run their companies and access things like stock markets, as Alibaba owner Jack Ma has discovered as he’s tried to float Ant Group on the Shanghai and Hong Kong exchanges. International banks are discovering this in Hong Kong as the national security law affects far more than ‘the few’ Carrie Lam promised.

Chinese policymakers talk about ‘reform and opening up’ and making China a better, more predictable place for foreign trade, investors and companies. But the government’s relentless drive to exert greater control over trade and economic partnerships and to intervene in unexpected ways is sending the opposite message—and not just to Australia.

China’s market is becoming more closed, more difficult and more unpredictable, not more open and reciprocal. And, for companies operating from jurisdictions whose governments are not on board with the policy directions and strategic imperatives of Xi’s government, market access is being used as a weapon. It’s a weapon designed to punish such governments, like Australia’s, to pressure them through domestic business lobbies that simply want sales to continue, and to intimidate other governments that might be contemplating similar policies.

Chinese state power and party control have popped the bubble of Australia’s China market boom. Business interests who say their ‘special relationships’ with Chinese partners show they can ‘solve the trade impasse’ simply can’t explain why such connections haven’t helped prevent Beijing’s actions to date, or why they might work now. Instead of wondering whether more nuance from our government or warmer personal relationships between Australian and Chinese ministers might be the answer, we need to recognise the fundamental change to the terms of access to the China market and plan and act accordingly.

Maybe the lonely exception here is our iron ore trade, simply because it’s a continuing structural need of China’s economy, at least until China manages its long-foreshadowed transition from a manufacturing and infrastructure-building economy to a services and consumption economy, or Brazil gets better at reliability, cost and scale.

The fact that Australia is not alone in experiencing the coercive shift in Beijing’s management of market access should help us understand that it’s not about window dressing around Australian policy and presentation, but about a fundamental change that’s beginning to affect every major economy and company engaging in the China market. Australia is ahead of this curve because of the speed of our export growth with China. We’ve made this problem worse for ourselves by failing to insulate our trade by doing the groundwork to develop and grow other markets.

But there’s little point in pining for 2012 or 2015 and seeking the future sketched out then by Gillard and Treasury. It was a mirage and it has evaporated, in parallel with the collapse in China’s soft power and trustworthiness across the populations of the world’s advanced economies.

The direction we need to take is pretty clear, even if it’s not easy. We need to make the China market matter less to us, just as it did for the sectors mentioned above only six years ago. Because this is such a recent phenomenon, we know we can change the structure and direction of trade in these items. And the more difficult the Chinese government makes it for us to access the China market, the more this will happen.

No single market can replace China, but wealthy consumers across the world want to buy more lobsters and more wine than the world can supply, and our commodities and resources are, as they were before the pandemic, high quality and well priced.

Making the China market matter less, ironically, is also the best way to reduce the likelihood the Chinese government will use our trade against us, because it makes that trade much less of a weapon. If 20% of our wine and lobster sales go to China in 2024, for example, bilateral trade will have returned to being more a simple calculation of mutual benefit that’s easier to divorce from politics and power.

Given the speed of the shift, maybe there’s a case here for structural adjustment packages for some of the affected industries. Government-to-government engagement to open and expand alternative markets with jurisdictions in which trust is high and with which we have opportunities in the post-Covid-19 world to build new partnerships that increase our resilience seem to not just make sense but to meet public expectations. Germany is an example here, as are South Korea, Taiwan and Japan.

Whether it’s the gold rush of the 1850s, the mining and mining investment booms of the early 2000s, or the China market boom of the past six years, Australians have never been much good at admitting the good times will end. But we’ve got a pretty good track record of managing the transition and finding new sources of prosperity when they do.

Solving global problems will require a new social contract

Every society rests on a web of norms, institutions, policies, laws and commitments to those in need of support. In traditional societies, such obligations are borne mostly by families and kin groups. In advanced economies, a greater share of the burden is placed on the state and markets (through health insurance and pensions). Yet even in the latter case, much of the social contract is still upheld by families (through unpaid care work), civil society (voluntary and charitable organisations) and employers (through benefits they’re required to provide to their employees).

The social contract is not synonymous with the welfare state. Rather, the welfare state refers to the dimensions of a social contract that are mediated through the political process and subsequent state action, either directly through taxation and public services or indirectly through laws requiring the private sector to provide certain benefits. As such, the welfare state is best understood not as a redistribution mechanism, but as a source of productivity and protection over the course of a person’s life. As John Hills of the London School of Economics has shown, most people contribute as much to the state as they receive in return.

Nonetheless, much of the anger that has come to define politics in the developed world is rooted in people’s sense of having not received what they are owed. Those born into disadvantage feel as though they never had a chance. Those living in rural areas believe that policymakers have overwhelmingly favoured cities. Native-born populations fear that immigrants are receiving benefits before they have paid their dues. Men sense that their historic privileges are eroding. Older people regard the young as ungrateful for past sacrifices, and the young increasingly resent the elderly for straining social-security programs and leaving a legacy of environmental destruction. All of this distrust and animosity is fodder for populists.

So, too, are the effects of technological change and globalisation. The integration of global supply chains has delivered huge gains to the middle classes in emerging economies and to the top 1% globally, but it has hollowed out the middle and working classes in advanced economies.

The conventional wisdom is that workers in advanced economies have had to sacrifice wages or social protections to compete with emerging-market labour, and that these pressures have intensified as capital has become more mobile. Worse, the social mobility that once made inequality politically tolerable has stalled or declined.

In principle, the provision of adequate insurance against economic displacement should make the pressures from technological change and globalisation manageable. But many aspects of today’s welfare states are still designed for the old economy, where male breadwinners paid into reliable pensions over the course of a lifetime, while women stayed at home to raise children and care for the young and the old.

For the first time in history, there are now more women in higher education than men around the world. Educated women have fewer children, are more likely to be in paid work, and will increasingly feel tensions between their participation in the labour market and their traditional caring responsibilities. Yet recent research from the International Monetary Fund shows that closing the gender gap has significant benefits for growth. The challenge, then, is to redefine the social contract so that women can make full use of their talents without any loss of social cohesion.

In advanced economies, this tension is at the centre of debates about childcare and declining birthrates. Societal ageing means that a shrinking working-age population must cover rapidly rising healthcare and pension costs. Worse, today’s working-age population already has less security than previous generations, owing to the decline of defined-benefit pensions and a lack of access to many employment benefits or training opportunities.

Likewise, climate change represents a breakdown of the intergenerational social contract. Over the past year, young people staged massive protests against an economic model that doesn’t take adequate account of the environment. As the evidence of an impending climate disaster mounts, so too has support for alternative economic models that would enable more sustainable development.

Once we have acknowledged these global challenges, we can begin to envision what a new social contract might look like. For example, education will need to occur earlier in life, when the foundation for subsequent learning is established, as well as later, to meet the demand for reskilling. It also will need to focus on tasks that complement what robots can do. Serious investments in reskilling—on the order of 1–2% of GDP, as in Denmark—must be central to any modernised social contract.

A new social contract also may need to provide a minimum income for all, but structured in a way that preserves the incentive to work and retrain. Earned income tax credits, mandatory training and work placements, and employment guarantees should all be considered. And to tap into the world’s growing pool of female talent, large investments will be needed to expand childcare and eldercare, provide shared parental leave, and counter the effects of formal and informal biases that place women at a disadvantage. For example, if benefits were made portable and provided pro rata, more workers would be able to rely on part-time work to balance other commitments.

As for sustainability, we need to adopt an entirely different way of thinking about ageing and the environment. If a shrinking labour force is going to have any chance of supporting an ageing population, the investments needed to boost future productivity must be made now. In the meantime, ageing populations may have to commit to working longer—with retirement ages pegged to life expectancy—and demanding less medicalised health care at the end of life. Finally, current and future environmental costs will have to be incorporated into economic decisions. We need massive investments in green technologies to transform cities, transportation and energy systems. Considered together, such a new social contract has the potential to restore a sense of hope and optimism about the future.

The indispensable dollar

Chinese and European aspirations to weaken the dominance of the US dollar as the global currency of choice have come to naught, with the latest global survey showing the greenback is on one side of 88% of all foreign currency transactions, an 18-year high.

The dollar’s ascendency gives the US administration an unrivalled ability to exercise coercion by imposing economic sanctions.

A new report by the United States Studies Centre’s Stephen Kirchner argues that the dominant role of the US dollar reflects the depth of US capital markets and the strength of US institutions and is likely to be long-lasting.

However, the paper warns that excessive use of economic sanctions will lead affected nations to develop workarounds.

The triennial survey of foreign exchange turnover conducted by the Bank for International Settlements showed the US dollar’s share had dropped to 84.9% at the beginning of the decade but has since gained ground at the expense of both the euro and the yen.

The euro was on one side of 32.3% of foreign exchange transactions this year, down from 39.0% in the 2010 survey, while the share of the yen dropped from 19.0% to 16.8%.

Only 4.3% of global foreign exchange deals involve China’s renminbi, significantly less than the 6.8% using the Australian dollar.

The foreign exchange market, which turns over US$6.6 trillion a day, is only one dimension of the US dollar’s dominance. It also accounts for 63% of outstanding debt securities (compared with 20% for the euro) and 40% of cross-border financial transactions.

The US dollar is used as the currency for invoicing more than three times as many global exports as America itself ships. About 70% of nations peg their own currencies in some way to the US dollar.

It is also the currency of choice for the world’s central banks, which use it for 62% of their foreign exchange reserves, although Kirchner argues that this status as a ‘reserve’ currency has little impact on the dollar’s ubiquitous use in global commerce. Rather it’s a reflection of the depth and liquidity of US capital markets and their supporting economic and political institutions.

When the euro was launched in 1999, many economists expected it to rival, or even supplant, the US dollar. The former head of international economics at the US Treasury, Fred Bergsten, expected the euro would match the US dollar within five to 10 years.

China’s central bank has been pursuing a strategy to internationalise the renminbi since 2006 when it argued it would enhance China’s international status and bring a ‘rise in power standing’. The International Monetary Fund included the renminbi in the basket of currencies used to determine the value of its ‘special drawing rights’ in 2016.

However, Kirchner argues that both the euro zone and China show that size alone will not deliver international status to a currency.

‘Only well-developed capital markets, backed by sound political institutions, relatively sound monetary and fiscal policy, property rights and the rule of law, can provide the underpinnings for a currency that is widely demanded outside its own borders’, he says.

‘[B]oth the euro zone and China are beset by chronically weak political and economic institutions that are also resistant to reform. The prospect that either the euro or RMB significantly displace the dollar in the global economy in the medium-term is close to zero.’

He says the euro has been a source of economic weakness rather than strength for its member economies by limiting the scope for exchange rate adjustment to absorb economic shocks. Euro-denominated assets are not seen by global investors as a safe haven in times of trouble because the monetary union is not backed by any common budget strategy or banking union.

Between 2012 and 2019, the euro’s share of global payments dived from 44% to 34%, while the European Central Bank’s own measure of its international role shows it has been in decline since 2006 and is virtually no greater now than it was at its birth 20 years ago.

The indispensability of the US dollar in global transactions gives Washington a powerful lever. US economic sanctions can prevent companies and individuals from accessing the US payments system to settle US dollar transactions.

‘Non-US banks rely on their relationships with US banks and their access to US-regulated dollar payments system infrastructure to effect international transactions on behalf of their clients’, the report says.

‘Russia, Iran, Venezuela and North Korea have been the subject of sanctions whose enforcement is made effective largely by the role of the US dollar in the global economy.’

However, the economic aggression is bringing some pushback. For example, Europe is moving to price its oil imports in euros, to facilitate continued purchases from Russia. With Iran, a special vehicle has been established so that European importers and exporters match their transactions on the European side of the border, while their Iranian counterparties do the same with their rials on their side.

‘If the US government were to abuse the role of the dollar as an instrument of international economic coercion, it might further foster the development of alternative, non-US dollar-based payments mechanisms’, the report says.

Australia’s booming trade with China will shape strategic policy

Diplomatic relations may have been strained, but Australia’s trade relationship with China is growing ever closer. The latest trade report shows that China was the destination for a record 40% of Australia’s exports in June.

It was only a little over three years ago that China’s share of Australia’s monthly exports hit 30%. A decade ago it was just 20%.

The last time a single country took such a large share of Australia’s merchandise exports was in 1952 when it was the United Kingdom. Japan’s share of Australian exports peaked at a third in the mid-1970s and is now down to 14%.

Supported by soaring sales of LNG and high prices for iron ore and coal, Australia’s earnings from the Chinese market rose by 27% in the year to June. That’s almost double the growth rate of other markets.

While the China trade balance is massively in Australia’s favour, imports of Chinese goods are also growing rapidly. Over the past financial year, our imports from China rose by 15%, while imports from everywhere else fell by 2%. Businesses on both sides of the trade are making big profits.

The intensity of the trade relationship worries strategists. ASPI Executive Director Peter Jennings has argued that China’s ‘economic dominance’ is having an impact on the government’s strategic thinking. ‘[W]e urgently need a strategy to diversify economic relations’, he says. There are concerns that China could exercise economic coercion over Australia.

China has a track record of bullying on trade. Lowy Institute China analyst Richard McGregor notes that Norway suddenly lost its Chinese salmon market when the Nobel Prize was awarded to a Chinese dissident, Philippine mangoes were left to rot after its government won an international court case over the South China Sea, Chinese tourism to South Korea was restricted after it agreed to host US missiles, and, most recently, Canadian canola has been penalised following Canada’s arrest of Huawei’s finance director.

There were suggestions Australian thermal coal exports to China were being restricted earlier this year as punishment for the Turnbull government’s foreign interference legislation. However, the customs delays soon spread to all thermal coal exporters and it was hard to isolate a political intent.

China is trying to both lift self-sufficiency in thermal coal (it already supplies 95% of its own coal for power stations) and reduce coal’s share in the overall energy market.

One result of Beijing’s push for reduced carbon pollution has been absolutely stunning growth in Australia’s sales of LNG to China. Commonwealth Bank commodities analyst Vivek Dhar says Australia’s LNG exports to China rose by 37% last year, compared with growth of 10% in sales to Japan and 13% in sales to South Korea. In June, China is overtook Japan as Australia’s biggest LNG market, something Dhar says he didn’t expect to happen for years.

This points to an important strategic truth: China is heavily dependent on raw material and energy supplies from Australia. China’s steel industry wouldn’t function without Australian iron ore and metallurgical coal. LNG has become an essential source of energy for the Chinese economy and the quick sea route to Australia makes it the preferred supplier. China’s industry would soon face a crisis in the event of any lasting disruption to the Australian shipping route.

Education—Australia’s fourth-largest export to China—is more vulnerable. The dependence of major universities, including the University of Sydney and the University of Melbourne, on Chinese enrolments for up to a third of their revenue leaves them exposed.

China values its access to Western universities and its middle classes place a premium on English-language education, giving a resilience to Chinese demand.

Education highlights the implausibility of any strategy to diversify the economic relationship. Sydney University vice chancellor Michael Spence claims that government funding is a bigger risk than foreign enrolments. However, even in a hypothetical world where government boosted education funding, a university would still take an enrolment from the next foreign student if it could. No business will readily turn away a customer.

One of the most striking features of Australia’s trade with China has been the growth of non-traditional exports. While the big three—iron ore, coal and LNG—account for more than two-thirds of merchandise exports to China, the combined value of the next 20 largest Australian exports has risen by more than 70% over the last five years and is more than Australia gets in total from any other market except Japan.

Some of these gains—for example, barley and beef—have been helped by the China–Australia free trade agreement, while others—such as pharmaceuticals, crayfish, wine and baby formula—reflect middle-class Chinese demand.

For both sides, it is good business, and that’s the driving force behind the entire trade relationship.

While the mercantilist approach of the US administration regards exports as good and imports as bad, economists concerned with consumer welfare emphasise the value of imports: it is access to goods and services of the best value that lifts living standards. Australian consumers have benefited from low-cost Chinese technology and household goods, while business competitiveness has been enhanced by access to low-cost Chinese industrial supplies.

The strength of the economic relationship does shape the government’s strategic options. Australia hasn’t followed the US’s freedom-of-navigation operations close to the Chinese-constructed islands in the South China Sea, for example. However, prosperity is in the national interest and the relationship has delivered that over the past 15 years.

The most immediate risks are more economic than strategic. The Chinese government faces a supremely challenging task in achieving a controlled slowing of an unsustainable growth rate without imperilling the ability of its state-owned companies and local governments to service their massive debts. The trade conflict with the US makes that task all the more difficult. Attempting to sustain growth with resource-intensive infrastructure investment may be reaching its limit.

Through nearly all of the past 15 years, it has been a sellers’ market for most of the things Australia supplies China. Australia’s terms of trade (export prices compared with import prices) have been sustained at a higher level than at any time in the last century. Although both sides are dependent on each other, the balance would shift in a downturn. It would become a buyers’ market and Australia could become more vulnerable to pressure from its largest customer.

Fintel Alliance: fighting financial crime and terror funding

Justice Minister Michael Keenan recently launched the Fintel Alliance, a public-private partnership combating money laundering and terrorism financing. The partnership is unique internationally, bringing together 19 public and private sector organisations to counter these dual threats.

Led by the financial intelligence agency, AUSTRAC, the alliance members include law enforcement and intelligence agencies, the Tax Office, and private sector companies including the big four banks and Macquarie Bank, Western Union and PayPal. The initiative responds to a significant weakness in Australia’s ability to fight financial crime and terrorism financing, underdeveloped processes to share information between the public and private sectors.

So how does it work? Co-located in an Operations Hub (PDF), intelligence analysts from alliance partners collaborate on projects, combining information, knowledge and perspectives on an issue. To begin with, the alliance will examine information from the Panama Papers (PDF) exploitation of Australian Cyber Online Reporting Network (PDF) data, and identification of money mules (PDF).

Multi-agency task forces to fight specific crimes have been very effective. Project Wickenby—a taskforce focused on international tax evasion ran from 2006 until mid-2015—resulting in 46 convictions and recovering $986 million in unpaid tax. Wickenby’s success was continued by the Serious Financial Crime Taskforce (beginning on 1 July 2015) which has already obtained 5 convictions and recouped nearly $100 million. Previously these task forces have been limited to government agency participation, with the private sector excluded. Bringing in the private sector under the same roof makes the Fintel Alliance unique in this area.

Private sector involvement’s critical because money is laundered, terrorist funds are raised and illicit money is moved through private sector service providers—including banks, money remitters, casinos and other gambling businesses.

That’s why many companies are obliged by law to adopt mitigation strategies to prevent their services being used for nefarious purposes. It’s also why private sector companies must provide reports on certain transactions and suspicious matters to AUSTRAC. This information has enormous intelligence value (PDF) for law enforcement.

Companies need information from government to help them identify suspicious matters and mitigate risks. To date government has provided some information but it’s been too limited and untimely. The alliance should greatly improve this flow.

Collating more information from a wider range of sources will build a more complete picture. Better information allows for better targeted monitoring and investigations, saving time, reducing unnecessary work, and boosting business and law enforcement productivity. And the sharing of information in near real time will significantly speed up processes.

But the alliance is about more than just intelligence. Government and private sector partners also collaborate in the Innovation Hub which allows partners to develop innovative solutions to mutual problems. For example, the rules do not need to be one-size-fits-all and can be tailored to counter the specific risks of particular services. So new rules responding to financial sector innovation can be designed with early input from those effected. And controls can be built into new services and systems. This will reduce regulatory cost to business. Technological innovation in customer identification and automated detection tools can also be explored. Developments can benefit all of industry, not just those involved in the partnership.

So the alliance offers great promise. But what opportunities should its stakeholders look for, and what will success look like over the coming years?

First, the alliance should focus on successful investigations leading to prosecutions and financial recovery in the three target areas: the Panama Papers, cybercrime, and money mules.

Second, creating a trusted system with a sense of common purpose will be important. As David Connery, then of ASPI, noted, this is key to optimal information sharing. Such a system will form the basis of successful public-private sector cooperation into the future.

Third, there is the opportunity to develop the skills and knowledge of financial intelligence analysts. This should happen organically when analysts from different agencies and companies work closely together in the Operations Hub. It will also be well supplemented by the new Financial Intelligence Analysts’ Course (PDF). Greater knowledge and tradecraft skills will improve analysts’ ability to detect financial crime and terrorism financing. There is also the opportunity to co-develop typologies and case studies to better understand criminal and terrorist methods. Sanitised versions could be released publicly for the benefit of all.

Opportunities exist for intelligence analysts to move from the private sector to government and vice versa, either permanently or by secondment.

Once operating successfully, Fintel Alliance should look to expand involvement to other domestic companies and industries and international partners, adding to the current UK National Crime Agency participation.

Integration and better exploitation of data held by partner organisations presents great opportunity, especially with advancements in big data analytics.

The government’s to be applauded for an innovative solution to enhancing information sharing in the fight against crime and terrorism. There’s still much to be done.

How much Europe can Europe tolerate?

Image courtesy of Pixabay user TheAndrasBarta.

This month the European Union will celebrate the 60th anniversary of its founding treaty, the Treaty of Rome, which established the European Economic Community. There certainly is much to celebrate. After centuries of war, upheaval, and mass killings, Europe is peaceful and democratic. The EU has brought 11 former Soviet-bloc countries into its fold, successfully guiding their post-communist transitions. And, in an age of inequality, EU member countries exhibit the lowest income gaps anywhere in the world.

But these are past achievements. Today, the Union is mired in a deep existential crisis, and its future is very much in doubt. The symptoms are everywhere: Brexit, crushing levels of youth unemployment in Greece and Spain, debt and stagnation in Italy, the rise of populist movements, and a backlash against immigrants and the euro. They all point to the need for a major overhaul of Europe’s institutions.

So a new white paper on the future of Europe by European Commission President Jean-Claude Juncker comes none too soon. Juncker sets out five possible paths: carrying on with the current agenda, focusing just on the single market, allowing some countries to move faster than others toward integration, narrowing down the agenda, and pushing ambitiously for uniform and more complete integration.

It’s hard not to feel sympathy for Juncker. With Europe’s politicians preoccupied with their domestic battles and the EU institutions in Brussels a target for popular frustration, he could stick his neck out only so far. Still, his report is disappointing. It sidesteps the central challenge that the EU must confront and overcome.

If European democracies are to regain their health, economic and political integration cannot remain out of sync. Either political integration catches up with economic integration, or economic integration needs to be scaled back. As long as this decision is evaded, the EU will remain dysfunctional.

When confronted with this stark choice, member states are likely to end up in different positions along the continuum of economic-political integration. This implies that Europe must develop the flexibility and institutional arrangements to accommodate them.

From the very beginning, Europe was built on a ‘functionalist’ argument: political integration would follow economic integration. Juncker’s white paper opens appropriately with a 1950 quote from the European Economic Community founder (and French prime minister) Robert Schuman: ‘Europe will not be made all at once, or according to a single plan. It will be built through concrete achievements which first create a de facto solidarity.’ Build the mechanisms of economic cooperation first, and this will prepare the ground for common political institutions.

This approach worked fine at first. It enabled economic integration to remain one step ahead of political integration—but not too far ahead. Then, after the 1980s, the EU took a leap into the unknown. It adopted an ambitious single-market agenda that aimed to unify Europe’s economies, whittling away at national policies that hampered the free movement not just of goods, but also of services, people, and capital. The euro, which established a single currency among a subset of member states, was the logical extension of this agenda. This was hyper-globalization on a European scale.

The new agenda was driven by a confluence of factors. Many economists and technocrats thought Europe’s governments had become too interventionist and that deep economic integration and a single currency would discipline the state. From this perspective, the imbalance between the economic and political legs of the integration process was a feature, not a bug.

Many politicians, however, recognized that the imbalance was potentially problematic. But they assumed functionalism would eventually come to the rescue: the quasi-federal political institutions needed to underpin the single market would develop, given sufficient time.

The leading European powers played their part. The French thought that shifting economic authority to bureaucrats in Brussels would enhance French national power and global prestige. The Germans, eager to gain France’s agreement to German reunification, went along.

There was an alternative. Europe could have allowed a common social model to develop alongside economic integration. This would have required integrating not only markets but also social policies, labor-market institutions, and fiscal arrangements. The diversity of social models across Europe, and the difficulty of reaching agreement on common rules, would have acted as a natural brake on the pace and scope of integration.

Far from being a disadvantage, this would have provided a useful corrective regarding the most desirable speed and extent of integration. The result might have been a smaller EU, more deeply integrated across the board, or an EU with as many members as today, but much less ambitious in its economic scope.

Today it may be too late to attempt EU fiscal and political integration. Less than one in five Europeans favor shifting power away from the member nation-states.

Optimists might say that this is due less to aversion to Brussels or Strasbourg per se than to the public’s association of ‘more Europe’ with a technocratic focus on the single market and the absence of an appealing alternative model. Perhaps emerging new leaders and political formations will manage to sketch out such a model and generate excitement about a reformed European project.

Pessimists, on the other hand, will hope that in the corridors of power in Berlin and Paris, in some deep, dark corner, economists and lawyers are secretly readying a plan B to deploy for the day when loosening the economic union can no longer be postponed.

China: economy-world versus security-world

Image courtesy of Flickr user Vin Crosbie

If China’s future course is the vital question, the answers in economy-world are different to those in security-world.

The versions of China offered in the two worlds clash in nature, form and quality.

In security-world, the worry is an ever stronger China.

In economy-world, the threat is a China that stumbles into a looming financial crisis of its own making.

Either world could deliver a belligerent China.

Security-world fears a confident China shouldering others aside and shaking the international system as it grabs for presumed prerogatives. Eco-world knows China as a mainstay of the international system and fears a stalling or shuddering China, losing its grip on prerogatives already earned.

The sky in each world is a different colour, yet ultimately these clashing realities must merge, if not reconcile.

At this bend in the river, we have more to fear in eco-world than what Beijing will do in security-world. Worry more about a weakened China.

Hold onto that thought as security-world prepares for South China Sea feeding frenzy on the decision from The Hague, expected to give China a mighty whack. Harken to the refrain of a frequent frenzied feeder lifting his eyes from the plate.

China’s behaviour in the South China Sea is deeply worrying. And this feeder has been feasting on it in the foreign affairs and defence debates of the Oz election, the US discussion of the menace confronting Asia’s ‘principled future’, China’s rumbling push back, and the security-world fear of Asia’s order fading as jaw-jaw slides the war-war way.

My argument is with myself. Blog world wants more than that, so let’s take issue with someone else. Step forward Alan Dupont, one of my guides in security-world for decades, who argues:

‘Those who dismiss the South China Sea dispute as a storm in teacup, or persist with the illusion that China will refrain from antagonising non-claimant states, need to think again. Far from de-escalating, this dispute is showing all the hallmarks of becoming the most serious security problem for Southeast Asia and Australia since the Vietnam War.’

Shaping as the biggest thing Southeast Asia has faced since Vietnam? Really?

Bigger than Cambodia’s civil war and ASEAN’s confrontation with Vietnam…the agony of Burma or East Timor…the China–Vietnam border war…the fall of Suharto and the possibility that Indonesia could disintegrate as a country?

The total death toll from all those events is in the hundreds of thousands. No body count yet from the South China Sea.

There are a lot of waypoints on the journey from storm in a teacup to the worst since Vietnam.

Australia hopes we are still closer to the teacup than full-on naval warfare. Canberra’s caution was captured in the exquisite moment when the Foreign Minister said Oz policy is to sail 12.1 nautical miles from China’s great mountains of sand. The exquisite bit is that point-one margin on top of 12 nautical miles. Proclaim loudly but push China gently,

Conflicting interests in the South China Sea mean disaster will arrive by accident and escalation will rest on disastrous miscalculation. What China does on Scarborough Shoal after The Hague judgement will show how much more miss and mess is being mixed into the calculation.

South China Sea is a lead indicator for China’s security behaviour. But it ain’t the whole game. Or even the biggest game.

Flip across to eco-world for a moment. China isn’t interested in tearing up this international rules-based order because it’s a winner.

China sits up top of eco-world and wants more; ideally more on its own terms. Beijing is a status quo tidal power. The status quo at home is sacrosanct, while the tidal shift elsewhere should be as slow as it is steady. The tide is shifting their way (riches, power, prestige) and they want it to keep flowing—gently.

In eco-world, China is the world’s second largest economy. Indeed, using purchasing power parity China passed the US to become Number One a year ago—no loud PPP victory polka from Beijing because it doesn’t want to offend Washington. China chairs the G20 and if Asia steers the world economy away from Brexit disaster, it’ll be led by China.

Consider two judgements from the different worlds.

In security-world, conflict with China in the South China Sea is a low-probability but high impact event; long odds that would deliver disaster.

In eco-world, the high impact, high probability event that is approaching with the inevitability of gravity is that China is going to have a financial reckoning. It might be a soft landing or a hard landing but judgement day—financial bust or abrupt slowdown—is a-comin’.

The Economist laid out the logic and figures for the coming debt bust that will crunch asset prices and the real economy, arguing that ‘a Chinese crisis is likely to be sharper and more sudden than Japan’s chronic malaise.’

We had a taste with China’s stock market panic last year—crashing correction presenting as cascading catastrophe. The Party has made the dreadful discovery that the market won’t obey orders.

No wonder President Xi is cracking down on dissent and purging hard. He’s yanking on the power levers that still work.

For Australia, a China crash is the biggest economic threat we face. Ditto for Asia. And just about everybody else.

Financial reality is catching up with China fast in eco-world. Pray that it lands soft not hard.

And that in security-world, the South China Sea stays closer to the teacup end of the scale.