Tag Archive for: Donald Trump

Trump’s Taiwan instinct: a threat to peace?

Image courtesy of Pixabay user Unsplash.

Donald Trump has signaled his interest in using America’s ‘One China’ policy as a bargaining chip in negotiations with China over economic policy (including currency manipulation). While this ‘instinct’ of his isn’t without merit, it could represent a threat to peace for which Australia must be fully prepared.

In brief, the ‘One China’ policy for Australia and most countries, but not the US, has meant formal diplomatic acceptance of the view that there’s only one China and that the People’s Republic of China (PRC) is recognised as the government of China. Since the declaration of the PRC government in 1949, after its defeat of the forces of the Republic of China (ROC) in the civil war on the mainland, the PRC and ROC have been locked in a complex military, political and diplomatic confrontation.

When the US conducted its negotiations with the PRC on normalisation of diplomatic relations—to switch formal diplomatic recognition from the ROC on Taiwan to the PRC on the mainland—Washington didn’t go as far as almost all other countries. Instead, it took note of China’s position to that effect. It refused to recognise Beijing’s entire formula for the ‘One China’ policy because China refused to formally commit to an exclusively peaceful solution to the stand-off. The US has maintained official representation in Taipei, along with a military alliance, ever since the switch of recognition in 1979.

In the very year that US recognised Beijing, China began its first serious peace overture to Taiwan, though the move didn’t bear fruit until the two warring parties met in 1992 and agreed themselves that there’s only one China—the mainland and Taiwan. But they didn’t address the question of which government was in charge. At that time, the ROC maintained the formal diplomatic fiction that it ruled all of China, including the entire Spratly Island group in the South China Sea.

Much has changed since then. Taiwan has become a democracy and China has become the island’s main investor and main trade partner. Economic integration has continued apace and China’s policy has been to bind Taiwan to China ‘with economic ropes.’ The significance and subtlety of many of the political and military maneuvering has changed over time.

The military threat from the PRC to Taiwan hasn’t disappeared but it has been pushed very far to the back burner. Taiwan has even resisted Washington’s efforts to push weapons purchases on it that its armed forces don’t want. But it values highly the US ‘alliance’ because China’s armed forces have become so powerful in the past two decades.

Since June 2016, Taiwan has again been under the Presidency of the pro-independence party, the Democratic Progressive Party (DPP). When it last held the presidency (2000–08), there was no major breach with China and, in fact, relations improved steadily. The Bush administration even enhanced its military exchanges with Taiwan, as did Japan, without serious impact on relations with China.

January 2017 presents us with a very different scenario. The Bush mantra on this issue was ‘I want good relations with China,’ no matter what we do with Taiwan. Trump, by contrast, appears to believe that he can use US recognition policy on Taiwan as a bargaining chip to gain concessions from Beijing in economic policy.

We can credit his instincts. The issue is so important to China that one might expect it would be prepared to make concessions to preserve the current US positions. But he’s misreading China’s leadership and national sentiment in that country, especially its armed forces.

When China agreed to the current US diplomatic position in 1972 and 1978, it did so from a position of severe relative weakness. That was four decades ago. While China today has some economic and military vulnerabilities that the United States could exploit in a Taiwan-related negotiation, the leaders in Beijing sees the country as powerful enough to get its way on Taiwan issues. They also see themselves as well within their rights to use all forms of state power to do so. Moreover, the US position established in the 1970s leaves that country almost no room for maneuver except outright recognition of Taiwan independence.

Australia’s response to any move by Trump away from the One China policy will include a calculation of siding with our major ally, and with the democratically-elected government of Taiwan. But we need a clear-eyed view of just how China, and Taiwan itself, might react to a threat of unravelling strategic stability in the Taiwan Strait. It’s that stability, forged in 1972, that brought a sort-of peace to all of East Asia and helped contain Soviet power until the USSR collapsed.

Modern China will use force when threatened. In the very year that the US granted it formal diplomatic recognition, China invaded Vietnam. Its armed forces currently train for an invasion of Taiwan. But China has many economic levers it can pull, to devastating effect, before it needs to consider use of armed force. China also has cyber warfare options against Taiwan and the US that didn’t exist until quite recently.

Australia’s planning must include a view on whether the risk of unravelling Asian strategic stability is worth followership of our major ally if it threatens the Taiwan consensus on which that stability is built.

JASTA: a poison pill for President Trump

Image courtesy of Pixabay user WikiImages.

In its dying moments the 114th Congress passed a bill, the Justice Against Sponsors of Terrorism Act, and then, for the only time in Barack Obama’s presidency, overrode his veto. The legislation negates the international legal principle of ‘sovereign immunity’ for governments, permitting parties injured by terrorist acts in the United States to sue foreign governments where complicity in an act of terrorism is proven.

That possibility already exists for states officially designated as sponsors of terrorism. Saudi Arabia isn’t one of these. However, the legislation has Riyadh right in the frame for the 9,000 victims (killed and injured), and their families, of the 9/11 attacks. The bill was passed on the 15th anniversary of that atrocity. 9/11 families’ and survivors’ organisations campaigned for JASTA for a long time, conscious of the US$2.7 billion compensation settlement in the case brought against Libya’s Gaddafi government for the Lockerbie bombing, which averaged $10 million for each affected family.

JASTA is a disaster. It has massive ramifications for Saudi–American relations, including bilateral collaboration in the struggle against fundamentalist terror. There’s also the clear prospect of copycat legislation in other countries aimed at American assets. As the EU delegation in the United States argued in September 2016:

State immunity is a central pillar of the international legal order. Any derogation from the principle of immunity bears the inherent danger of causing reciprocal action by other states and an erosion of the principle as such. The latter would put a burden on bilateral relations between states as well as the international order as a whole.

They know whereof they speak. In Belgium in 1999, a new law gave its courts jurisdiction for crimes against humanity anywhere in the world. Bush administration officials then had complaints filed against them, prompting a threat from Washington to remove the NATO headquarters from Brussels. The Belgian law was repealed in 2003.

JASTA was strongly supported by Democratic Senator Chuck Schumer of New York. But the real driving force was the Republicans in the House and Senate, who were out to embarrass Obama, extracting advantage in the lead-up to November’s elections. Candidate Trump enthusiastically attacked Obama for his subsequently overridden veto. Republican senators even attacked Obama for not doing enough to stop them!

Now the problem is in Trump’s lap.

No evidence of official Saudi collusion in the 9/11 attacks has emerged in the years since, including in the recently published secret parts of the comprehensive official report on the investigation of the attack. However, pursuit of that claim, and any others yet to be made, could place before the courts comprehensive details of American intelligence collections, putting at risk critical collaboration with American partners in the Middle East and elsewhere. Saudi investment in the United States is around US$800 billion. They’ve threatened to sell up—not an easy task. However, they could determine to no longer peg the riyal to the US dollar, which they have done to their cost. As a group of former defence and intelligence leaders wrote to President Obama and Congress: ‘[The Saudis] have been willing to pay a steep price in the form of declining dollar reserves for the sake of their alliance with the United States.’ If they were to conclude that the peg served no strategic purpose and removed it, ‘such a development would, of course, directly undermine the dollar in global currency markets’.

More to the point, copycat legislation in other countries would adversely affect the United States, which has more assets spread across the globe. US officials conducting global counterterrorism operations, including drone, air and special forces actions, would be vulnerable once sovereign immunity was removed.

It isn’t easy to see Congress reversing itself. Likewise, it’s not easy to see President Trump, with his well-known proclivity to ‘double down’ on positions he has taken, do otherwise on this. There’s no real deal here to be had. Whatever one’s thoughts on the Saudi Kingdom, the balance of advantage in the relationship lies heavily with the US. The Saudis have been a strong supporter in the struggle with terror and they’re also a big defence customer of the US. Under Obama, around $50 billion worth of defence equipment was acquired by the Saudis—three times the amount under his predecessor.

The Republicans in Congress, having perceived problems with the legislation, undertook to examine the issue in the new Congress. The JASTA legislation leaves in place a capacity to delay court actions. The administration can intervene to assert that it is trying to resolve the issues involved in litigation, with the relevant government. The stay in proceedings lasts six months and is renewable. That will pit the aggrieved party effectively against their own government. It will be a major impediment to building community trust in government endeavours if the government is effectively arguing against its citizens.

Congress has kicked a massive ‘own goal’ in an arena where American leadership is crucial. We have personnel in the field in this struggle and we need to raise it with the new administration, and with Congress, at the earliest opportunity.

Trumping Australia’s American alliance

Image courtesy of Pixabay user fshnextension.

Donald Trump will stress test America’s alliance with Australia. He’s going to pressure lots of other areas—the alliance will get its share. Australia will strive to confine disagreements. Canberra wants differences to be matters of degree, not division. Heaven forbid clashing core interests test alliance fundamentals. As ever, Australia will cling to the alliance. But Trumpism will push limits and unbalance assumptions. The 45th President promises to test purposes, and that might just go to questions of principle. Heaven forbid.

As the roller coaster is inaugurated, this is the perfect moment for a book entitled Australia’s American Alliance, the second in MUP’s Defence series from the ANU’s Strategic and Defence Studies Centre. The blurbage is strong with this one. John Howard calls it a ‘detailed analysis of a relationship of enduring importance’. One of Canberra’s wise owls, Allan Gyngell, goes bigger: ‘No book I know comes closer to illuminating the mysteries and identifying the challenges of Australia’s most important external relationship.’

Based on a treaty that had its 66th birthday in September, the alliance’s endurance is built on adaptability. Trump will test that resilience. Australia, though, has worried about US reliability and commitment for all 66 years. As Stephan Fruhling notes, Australia learned to live with a great ally that was ‘often fickle in its strategic attentions’. Today, the US focuses on where Australia lives. We got what we wished for. Fruhling summarises the new era’s challenges:

  • Can Australia be more successful than in the past in using its geographic position to influence the US?
  • Must Australia embrace greater political-military institutionalisation of the alliance?
  • Does Australia want to bind itself ever-closer to US strategic commitments in the region?

Australia once fretted that ANZUS didn’t match the commitments of NATO. The change in Canberra thinking long preceded Trump’s blasts at NATO free riders. Andrew Carr sees an alliance role reversal. The ‘open and informal structure of ANZUS’ was ‘created to preserve US freedom of action’. Today, it’s Australia that worries about ‘burdens and entanglement’.

The obsessive gaze Australia long bestowed on the US—the bilateral blinkers—broadens. Now, Canberra worries about what the alliance means for Australia in Asia. The endurance of the alliance, Carr states, will rest on Australia’s ‘ultimate judgement’ about the US as a ‘long-term Asia-Pacific power’.

Trump’s trashing of the Trans-Pacific Partnership shows the clashing orbits of economic world and security world—Ecworld versus SecWorld. Looking from EcWorld, Amy King starts with the insight of another Canberra wise owl, Stuart Harris. Since WW2 the US and Oz have agreed on the principles of the international economic order; in practice, they’ve ‘frequent bilateral conflict within those principles’. Hello, Donald!

King concludes that Australia can’t run an economic policy narrowly based on its alliance, and must seek EcWorld-SecWorld alignment:

  • Keeping the US engaged in Asia
  • Managing the ‘order transition’ of China’s economic rise
  • Maintaining the open, liberal, non-discriminatory order that most benefits Australian trade

These are among the six chapters in the book’s first two sections on strategic policy. Part III on ‘Mechanics of alliance cooperation’ illuminates the entrails, with John Blaxland (military cooperation), James Goldrick (interoperability), Michael Wesley (intelligence), and Richard Brabin-Smith (kit and capability).

Wesley on the ‘unprecedented intelligence intimacy’—intelligence as the ‘strategic essence’ of the alliance, as Des Ball put it—and Brab Smith on ‘the US command of the application of science and technology to warfare’, offer rich accounts of what Australia gets from the alliance. The science and the gear and the intelligence are as important as the Marines. The ties bind in myriad ways.

The final chapters—Part IV on ‘Managing trade-offs’—consist of Kim Beazley (what the alliance means for Oz sovereignty), Peter Dean (Oz strategic culture and way of war), and Brendan Taylor (Australia and the US in Asia). Each is strong; Beazley hits it out of the park.

Beazley starts with the paradox that the alliance today ‘involves a more intense relationship than it did when the Berlin Wall came down and the Cold War ended’. He believes that ‘depth and robustness’ is based on a calculation of the alliance’s value to Australia’s ultimate security. Beazley’s analysis suggests the alliance is Trump-proof (my term, not his).

Beazley emphasises the 21st Century ‘development of a seamless interconnection’ between Australia–US military and intelligence services: ‘The depth of that connection has the capacity to endure through potentially sharp shifts in the orientation of future administrations. It is our version of a “deep state” without the sinister attributes applicable to the military and intelligence establishment in authoritarian regimes.’

Serving the deep state as Australia’s previous ambassador to Washington, Beazley records how the embassy manages 400 military purchase projects. Each working day Australia spends $13 million on American defence industry products. What that buys is displayed in the air defence system for Australia’s approaches: ‘the best we have had,’ Beazley argues, ‘and it is regionally decisive’.

Australia used to think about interoperability. Now, Beazley writes, the US talks force integration: ‘The trajectory of our mutual military collaboration will challenge thinking about Australian sovereignty.’

The challenge now has a president. Trump will force Australia to look hard at our prized possession.

Pax Americana in the time of Trump

Image courtesy of Flickr user Evan Guest.

Since he launched his presidential bid more than 18 months ago, Donald Trump has confounded prediction and eluded persuasive analysis. On Saturday morning (4am AEST), at the age of 70, he takes the office so many people thought he never could reach. He was, the conventional wisdom insisted, too crude, too rude, too lewd and too much of a buffoon to be taken seriously for high office.

But here he is, assuming the 45th presidency of the United States, his critics still at a loss as to how to assess and even properly understand the core governing philosophy of this former reality television star and real estate magnate.

Take his foreign policy views.

Trump says US military interventions in the Middle East all too often make a bad situation worse. But he also wants to destroy Islamic State, which presumably implies some sort of US military role in the Arab world.

He rails against Iran, its nuclear ambitions and its attempts to create a Shia crescent in the Persian Gulf. Yet he supports the Russian-backed campaign to embolden the Assad regime that is in cahoots with the Mullahs, who are funding the Shia militias against Sunni jihadists in Iraq.

He has questioned whether Washington should provide security guarantees to Japan and South Korea. Yet he has walked back his criticisms of Asian treaty allies in recent months and suggested he might enhance US diplomatic and security ties with Taiwan that Beijing considers part of China.

Such contradictions aside, a few things are clear about Trump’s world view, and they are strikingly at odds with that of the US foreign policy establishment. Here are four of them:

First, unlike most of his post-war predecessors and perhaps even his senior cabinet officials, Trump does not embrace the notion of American global leadership, AKA a ‘Pax Americana’. For the incoming president, trying to dominate the world and push democracy on other nations has been a disaster, especially in the Middle East.

Although his message of “America First” upsets foreign policy elites, who have dominated public discourse in Washington since the collapse of Soviet Communism, it has resonated with a war-weary public. Remember he won the November 8 election in part because he bucked both major parties on this issue. He opposed costly, bloody and pointless wars in the Middle East while he called for a new understanding with the Russians.

Second, Trump is no foreign policy idealist. Unlike most presidents since Woodrow Wilson, he does not talk the language of exceptionalism, the belief that America has a special mission to redeem the world. Although he is unlikely to be aware of AJP Taylor, given his previous criticisms of both Democrat and Republican foreign policy, Trump would no doubt subscribe to the British historian’s adage that the road to hell is paved with good intentions.

For example, in Iraq, the Bush administration’s toppling of the brutal Saddam Hussein regime cost blood, treasure and credibility, destroyed the regional balance of power and helped create the Sunni jihadists that later morphed into Islamic State. In Libya, the Obama administration helped bring down the horrific Gaddafi regime, which produced a failed state and a wonderland for jihadists. Given all this, a policy of restraint and discrimination is sensible. The flip-side, though, is that Trump is unlikely to place a premium on values and multilateralism in his foreign policy deliberations.

Third, Trump wants to go to considerable lengths to improve relations with Russia. Indeed, he is so deeply committed to ending the new Cold War that détente will be one of his first priorities. But he faces hostile opposition to any rapprochement from Democrats and Republicans as well as military and intelligence figures. Even Trump’s nominees for Defense and the CIA sounded hawkish in their recent confirmation hearings.

Democrats are using an intelligence report into hacking to blame Vladimir Putin for Trump’s victory last November. Other anti-Russian pundits and politicians are using a dodgy dossier that implies Trump is a Kremlin stooge—or at least the controversy surrounding its recent media release—to undermine his Russian policy and potentially his presidency.

Fourth, Trump opposes various free trade agreements, including NAFTA and the TPP. Again, it’s difficult to deny his position’s democratic legitimacy: many blue-collar workers in rust-belt states that won the election for Trump blame globalisation for their stagnant wages, rising inequality and lost jobs in recent decades.

In reality, most of the economic dislocation is due to technological change and innovation. It is also far from clear how the new administration can bring back manufacturing jobs from low-wage, fast-growing East Asia. If anything, imposing a 45 per cent tariff on China, as Trump proposed during the campaign, could precipitate higher prices for the textiles, clothing and car sectors, which would hurt the very constituency he is ostensibly trying to assist. Moreover, a trade war could precipitate a regional recession, which is hardly in America’s national interest.

What then for Australia?

We are still the epitome of a satisfied, status quo state: well-endowed, stable middle power, with a modest population enjoying an enviable share of the world’s wealth and advantages. We have every reason to assume that any radical change in the existing state of the region’s economic and strategic affairs will diminish rather than enhance our position.

That means Canberra should concentrate on regional issues, not global; recognise that the UN is useful for our interests and therefore not to be unduly weakened; and insist that neither Washington nor Beijing upset the delicate regional equilibrium that has served the interests of Australia and the region for so long. In other words, we should stay on the American bandwagon, but not sign onto every Trump initiative.

All the more so given that the new president is an erratic character who is strikingly ignorant of the world—a potentially deadly combination. His foreign policy might start out as discriminating and cautious, reflecting the widespread public belief that America, as John Quincy Adams put it in 1821, “goes not abroad, in search of monsters to destroy”.

But given his temperament and lack of any core governing philosophy, as well as his genuine concern for US dignity and honour as he interprets them, it would be the easiest thing in the world for an adversary to taunt and goad him out of any sense of realism. After that, who knows where America might end up? In these circumstances, Trump should not expect lapdog obedience from Canberra.

The industry cart and the strategic horse

Image courtesy of Pixabay user Life-Of-Pix.

The Australian Naval Institute recently published the inaugural edition of its Australian Naval Review. I was pleased to be asked to contribute to the first issue, and subscribers to the Institute will be able to read my paper Australia’s naval shipbuilding plans: guided by strategy or industry? I set out to examine the stated rationale for the government’s ambitious program of naval ship and submarine building, and to test that against the timeframes we’ve been told to expect from the nation’s shipyards.

The central idea in the paper—that there’s a mismatch between Australia’s strategic and defence industry timeframes—won’t be much of a surprise to dedicated Strategist readers. I’ve made the point before, and Mark and I have made the same point about the future submarines.

To see why there’s a problem, have a look at these excerpts from the 2000, 2009 and 2016 Defence White Papers:

DWP 2000

‘China, as the country with the fastest growing security influence in the region, is an increasingly important strategic interlocutor for Australia.’

DWP 2009

‘In Northeast Asia, China is likely to … continue … its foreshadowed core military modernisation. Over the long term, this could affect the strategic reach and global postures of the major powers. …Any future that might see a potential contraction of US strategic presence in the Asia-Pacific region, with a requirement for allies and friends to do more in their own regions, would adversely affect Australian interests, regional stability and global security.’

DWP 2016

‘While China will not match the global strategic weight of the United States, the growth of China’s national power, including its military modernisation, means China’s policies and actions will have a major impact on the stability of the Indo-Pacific to 2035. China’s Navy is now the largest in Asia. By 2020 China’s submarine force is likely to grow to more than 70 submarines.’

In the 15 years between the 2000 and 2016 white papers, the Australian government’s assessment of China’s increasing capabilities went from being almost incidental to having ‘a major impact’ on the region’s stability in the next two decades. Consistent with that, last year’s White Paper worried about the stability of the Indo–Pacific in 2035.

But on current plans, the first of Australia’s future submarines won’t be commissioned much before 2035. And it’ll be ‘around 2050’ before the RAN submarine fleet will reach 12 boats. Meanwhile, the PLA-N will likely have ‘more than 70 submarines’ just four years from now. If the Australian government’s taking the intelligence agencies’ strategic assessments which underpin white paper discussions seriously, it’s not obvious from those plans.

If there’s a strategic shock of some kind, such as escalation of the current territorial disputes in the South or East China Seas, or a conflict sparked by North Korea, we could find ourselves wanting more defence capability much sooner than is currently planned. In that case, we’d have two broad options. We could try to increase the local production rate, with all the challenges of suddenly finding the required skills and capacity in a local industry that’d been gearing up for a long steady production run. Or we could supplement local production with purchases from overseas suppliers, but at a time when other nations will presumably also be in the market for equipment coming off their production lines. Either way, we’d struggle to acquire capability quickly enough for it to play a role in whatever contingency played out.

Or we could be lucky, and the region’s strategic shifts could play out benignly. It might be, for example, that the ‘nine-dash line’ in the South China Sea is the limit of China’s ambition. When the area’s secured to China’s satisfaction, perhaps it’ll get on with business and a ‘new normal’ strategic equilibrium will emerge. In that case, our leisurely timetable for fleet recapitalisation will be acceptable—and future governments could even find ourselves revising our plans for fleet expansion downwards.

Whichever way you look at it, we’re in a nowhere situation at the moment. Australia’s strategic rhetoric is pro-ANZUS and pro-military expansion because we’re worried about the next 20 years. We also want a steady-state industrial base for our naval ship requirements. The trouble is that we can’t have it all. Something will have to give—either the industry cart has to go back behind the strategy horse, or we need to rethink our strategy.

Let me finish this piece with a new thought. One possible strategy change, which would alter our defence requirements significantly, would be rethinking ANZUS. DWP 2016 emphasised shoring up the alliance, and assessed that the US will be both willing and able to act in ways consonant with our interests. Up until recently Australian strategists have worried about a potential cooling of American commitment. But, like Goldilocks, we’re discovering that our porridge could also be too hot. We’ve already seen hints of that, with unhelpful American musings about unilaterally changing the decades-old ‘one China’ policy, or by implicitly threatening force in the South China Sea. If that continues, we need to think hard about how we position ourselves. The worst case is that the United States unnecessarily precipitates a conflict, either by design or by misadventure.

Lessons from the populist revolt

Image courtesy of Flickr user Phillip.

The election of Donald Trump in the United States and the triumph of Brexit in the United Kingdom—the two political earthquakes of 2016—resulted from the failure of elites to grasp the discontent roiling politics in democracies around the world. The populist revolt marked the rejection of a technocratic approach to politics incapable of understanding the resentments of voters who feel the economy and the culture have left them behind.

Some denounce populism as little more than a racist, xenophobic reaction against immigrants and multiculturalism. Others view it as a protest against the job losses brought about by global trade and new technologies. But to see only the bigotry in populist protest, or to view that protest only in economic terms, misses the fact that the upheavals of 2016 stemmed from the establishment’s inability to address—or even adequately recognize—genuine grievances.

The populism ascendant today is a rebellion against establishment parties generally, but center-left parties have suffered the greatest casualties. This is mainly their own fault. In the US, the Democratic Party has embraced a technocratic liberalism more congenial to the professional classes than to the blue-collar and middle-class voters who once constituted its base. A similar predicament faces Britain’s Labour Party.

Before they can hope to win back public support, progressive parties must rethink their mission and purpose. To do so, they should learn from the populist protest that has displaced them—not by emulating its xenophobia and strident nationalism, but by taking seriously the legitimate grievances with which these sentiments are entangled. And that means recognizing that the grievances are about social esteem, not only about wages and jobs.

Progressive parties need to grapple with four main issues:

Income inequality. The standard response is to call for greater equality of opportunity—retraining workers; improving access to higher education; and combating discrimination. This is the meritocratic promise that those who work hard and play by the rules should be able to rise as far as their talents will take them.

But for many, this promise rings hollow. Even in the US, with its long-cherished dream of upward mobility, those born to poor parents tend to stay poor as adults. Of those born in the bottom fifth of the income scale, 43% will remain there, and only 4% will make it to the top fifth.

Progressives should reconsider the assumption that social mobility is the answer to inequality. They should reckon directly with inequalities of wealth and power, rather than rest content with efforts to help people ascend a ladder whose rungs are growing further and further apart.

Meritocratic hubris. The problem runs deeper. The relentless emphasis on seeking a fair meritocracy, in which social positions reflect effort and talent, has a morally corrosive effect on the way we interpret our success (or lack thereof). The belief that the system rewards talent and hard work encourages the winners to regard their success as their own doing, a measure of their virtue—and to look down upon the less fortunate.

Those who lose out may complain that the system is rigged, or be demoralized by the belief that they alone are responsible for their failure. When combined, these sentiments yield a volatile brew of anger and resentment, which Trump, though a billionaire, understands and exploits. Where Barack Obama and Hillary Clinton speak constantly of opportunity, Trump offers blunt talk of winners and losers.

Democrats like Obama and Clinton have difficulty understanding the hubris a meritocracy can generate, and the harsh judgment it renders on those without a college degree. This is why one of the deepest divides in American politics today is between those with and without post-secondary education.

The dignity of work. The loss of jobs to technology and outsourcing has coincided with a sense that society accords less respect to working-class occupations. As economic activity has shifted from making things to managing money, with hedge fund managers and Wall Street bankers receiving outsize rewards, the esteem accorded work in the traditional sense has become fragile and uncertain.

New technology may further erode the dignity of work. Some Silicon Valley entrepreneurs anticipate a time when robots and artificial intelligence will render many of today’s jobs obsolete. To ease the way for such a future, they propose paying everyone a basic income. What was once conceived as a safety net for all citizens is now offered as a way to soften the transition to a world without work. Whether to welcome or resist such a world is a question that will be central to politics in the coming years. To think it through, political parties will have to grapple with the meaning of work and its place in a good life.

Patriotism and national community. Free-trade agreements and immigration are the most potent flashpoints of populist fury. On one level, these are economic issues. Opponents argue that they threaten local jobs and wages, while proponents maintain that they help the economy in the long run. But the passion evoked by these issues suggests that something more is at stake.

Workers who believe that their country cares about cheap goods and cheap labor more than it cares about its own people’s job prospects feel betrayed, and they often express it in ugly ways: hatred of immigrants, nativist vilification of Muslims and other ‘outsiders,’ and demands to ‘take back our country.’

Liberals reply by condemning the odious rhetoric and insisting on the virtues of mutual respect and multicultural understanding. But this principled response, though valid, fails to address some big questions implicit in the populist complaint. What is the moral significance, if any, of national borders? Do we owe more to our fellow citizens than we owe citizens of other countries? In a global age, should we cultivate national solidarity or aspire to a cosmopolitan ethic of universal human concern?

Establishment elites, especially in Europe and the US, are now confronting the consequences of their failure to address these questions. The populist revolt highlights the need to rejuvenate democratic public discourse, to address the big questions people care about, including moral and cultural issues.

Disentangling legitimate grievances from the intolerant aspects of populist protest is no easy matter. But it is important to try. Creating a politics that can respond to these grievances is the most pressing political challenge of our time.

How Eastern Europe blew up the West

OLYMPUS DIGITAL CAMERA

Like the rise of Soviet communism and both World Wars, the Western liberal order’s apparent collapse in 2016 could turn out to be yet another historic upheaval that began in Eastern Europe. Hungarian Prime Minister Viktor Orbán’s brand of ‘illiberal democracy’ was quickly adopted by Poland’s de facto ruler, Jarosław Kaczyński, and is now making inroads in the heart of the West—first with the United Kingdom’s ‘Brexit’ referendum, and then with Donald Trump’s victory in the United States’ presidential election.

Meanwhile, Turkey’s nascent democracy has already given way to Recep Tayyip Erdoğan’s strongman rule, and the Philippines is now led by a populist authoritarian, Rodrigo Duterte. As we head into 2017, something is clearly rotten in the state of democracy.

It may seem unlikely that Orbán and Kaczyński—who both trained as lawyers under their countries’ communist regimes—have become globally influential political entrepreneurs. But their political project has all the features of what management research recommends for a successful innovation strategy. Like many disruptive products and popular brands, illiberal democracy does not try to please everyone; rather, it targets a carefully selected segment of ‘voter-customers,’ and gives them exactly what they want.

When Hillary Clinton called Trump’s supporters a ‘basket of deplorables,’ she quite accurately described one segment of the political market that Orbán’s innovation targets. But the illiberal democrat speaks not only to reactionaries eager to restore traditional social hierarchies, but also to working-class voters fearful of unemployment and downward mobility. The rest of society—ethnic, religious, and ideological minorities, including the urban ‘creative class’—then forms the opposition.

Illiberal democracy subverts the idea—held by European social democrats and American Democrats since the Civil Rights era—that working-class and minority voters should forge a progressive alliance to counter conservatives. Intellectually, such a ‘stronger together’ alliance makes sense; but it has three major flaws that Orbán and Kaczyński have exploited.

First, the economic interests of white (or native) working-class voters and those of minorities are often not aligned, because they are competing with one another for jobs and social benefits. This is especially true when slow growth turns the division of the economic pie into a zero-sum game. When funds are limited, should the Hungarian government spend money on educating Roma children, or on retraining displaced ethnic Hungarian workers?

Second, working-class voters often adhere to traditional conservative values. While a farmer in Eastern Poland or a factory worker in Michigan might be persuaded to support gay rights or women’s empowerment in exchange for economic redistribution, working-class voters have not supported such causes in large numbers.

Illiberal democracy is effective because it disentangles desired goods from unwanted add-ons, which is the essence of modern business innovation. Just as Airbnb allows us to find lodging without unnecessary hotel frills, illiberal democrats offer working-class voters economic help with no civil-rights strings attached.

Third, in many electorates, members of a social majority seem to value vilification of minorities as an intrinsic good, irrespective of wealth transfers. And as Yale University’s Amy Chua and others have shown, targeting minorities can be a highly effective tool for political mobilisation.

In the business world, it is widely understood that successful products are not just useful; they also provide customers with a distinct experience. In illiberal democracy, that experience relies on the spectacle of denigrating various ‘others.’ Indeed, many businesses, such as the companies that produce violent video games and reality-TV shows, have similarly exploited our basest instincts. Trump’s reality-TV show The Apprentice probably taught him how effective sowing division can be as a political-marketing tool.

Orbán’s insight, taken up by Kaczyński, was that an illiberal coalition comprising the working class and social reactionaries may be more viable than the old progressive project. Meanwhile, Hungary and Poland were ideal ‘early adopters’ of this innovation, because both countries are ethnically homogeneous, which makes minorities particularly weak and vulnerable.

But illiberal-democratic politics can also win elections in diverse societies such as the US. Like many successful products, illiberal democracy offers voters a fundamentally straightforward value proposition. Contrary to progressive agendas, the illiberal message is easy to understand, not only because it is often mendaciously simple, but also because its two target groups’ conservative cultural values inherently align.

Moreover, illiberal democracy can ignore issues that it considers to be non-essential, such as human rights and the rule of law: its only imperative is to satisfy its customers. More surprisingly, illiberal democrats also do not seem to be overly concerned about economic growth. Hungary had a relatively robust recovery after the 2008 recession, but its economy is now slowing; and in both Poland and post-Brexit UK, the high economic costs of illiberal democracy are already apparent. If Trump pursues his promised trade protectionism in 2017, he will likely push the entire world into recession.

This could be illiberal democrats’ fatal flaw, or it could represent their most daring political bet of all. Building a dynamic, creative economy in a closed society may not even be possible, but this does not matter if electorates in mid- and high-income countries no longer consider growth to be as important as identity.

Like a lousy seat on a low-cost airline, or the frustration of assembling IKEA furniture, illiberal-democratic electorates may regard economic stagnation as an acceptable price to pay for a more familiar world—one where the state guarantees the dominant in-group’s sense of belonging and dignity, at the expense of ‘others.’

Those of us who have lived in Orbán and Kaczyński’s world understand that illiberal democracy is no temporary aberration. It has all the hallmarks of a carefully conceived, innovative political strategy that may prove to be sustainable. Indeed, in a few decades we might look back and wonder how liberal democracy, with all its complexities and internal tensions, managed to hold on for so long—unless, that is, progressives treat 2016 as a wake-up call, and finally start to innovate, too.

Donald Trump and the Kindleberger trap

4707210329_9a3eb170fb_z

As US President-elect Donald Trump prepares his administration’s policy toward China, he should be wary of two major traps that history has set for him. The ‘Thucydides Trap,’ cited by Chinese President Xi Jinping, refers to the warning by the ancient Greek historian that cataclysmic war can erupt if an established power (like the United States) becomes too fearful of a rising power (like China). But Trump also has to worry about the ‘Kindleberger Trap’: a China that seems too weak rather than too strong.

Charles Kindleberger, an intellectual architect of the Marshall Plan who later taught at MIT, argued that the disastrous decade of the 1930s was caused when the US replaced Britain as the largest global power but failed to take on Britain’s role in providing global public goods. The result was the collapse of the global system into depression, genocide, and world war. Today, as China’s power grows, will it help provide global public goods?

In domestic politics, governments produce public goods such as policing or a clean environment, from which all citizens can benefit and none are excluded. At the global level, public goods—such as a stable climate, financial stability, or freedom of the seas—are provided by coalitions led by the largest powers.

Small countries have little incentive to pay for such global public goods. Because their small contributions make little difference to whether they benefit or not, it is rational for them to ride for free. But the largest powers can see the effect and feel the benefit of their contributions. So it is rational for the largest countries to lead. When they do not, global public goods are under-produced. When Britain became too weak to play that role after World War I, an isolationist US continued to be a free rider, with disastrous results.

Some observers worry that as China’s power grows, it will free ride rather than contribute to an international order that it did not create. So far, the record is mixed. China benefits from the United Nations system, where it has a veto in the Security Council. It is now the second-largest funder of UN peacekeeping forces, and it participated in UN programs related to Ebola and climate change.

China has also benefited greatly from multilateral economic institutions like the World Trade Organization, the World Bank, and the International Monetary Fund. In 2015, China launched the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank, which some saw as an alternative to the World Bank; but the new institution adheres to international rules and cooperates with the World Bank.

On the other hand, China’s rejection of a Permanent Court of Arbitration judgment last year against its territorial claims in the South China Sea raises troublesome questions. Thus far, however, Chinese behavior has sought not to overthrow the liberal world order from which it benefits, but to increase its influence within it. If pressed and isolated by Trump’s policy, however, will China become a disruptive free rider that pushes the world into a Kindleberger Trap?

Trump must also worry about the better-known Thucydides Trap: a China that seems too strong rather than too weak. There is nothing inevitable about this trap, and its effects are often exaggerated. For example, the political scientist Graham Allison has argued that in 12 of 16 cases since 1500 when an established power has confronted a rising power, the result has been a major war.

But these numbers are not accurate, because it is not clear what constitutes a “case.” For example, Britain was the dominant world power in the mid-nineteenth century, but it let Prussia create a powerful new German empire in the heart of the European continent. Of course, Britain did fight Germany a half-century later, in 1914, but should that be counted as one case or two?

World War I was not simply a case of an established Britain responding to a rising Germany. In addition to the rise of Germany, WWI was caused by the fear in Germany of Russia’s growing power, the fear of rising Slavic nationalism in a declining Austria-Hungary, as well as myriad other factors that differed from ancient Greece.

As for current analogies, today’s power gap between the US and China is much greater than that between Germany and Britain in 1914. Metaphors can be useful as general precautions, but they become dangerous when they convey a sense of historical inexorableness.

Even the classical Greek case is not as straightforward as Thucydides made it seem. He claimed that the cause of the second Peloponnesian War was the growth of the power of Athens and the fear it caused in Sparta. But the Yale historian Donald Kagan has shown that Athenian power was in fact not growing. Before the war broke out in 431 BC, the balance of power had begun to stabilise. Athenian policy mistakes made the Spartans think that war might be worth the risk.

Athens’ growth caused the first Peloponnesian War earlier in the century, but then a Thirty-Year Truce doused the fire. Kagan argues that to start the second, disastrous war, a spark needed to land on one of the rare bits of kindling that had not been thoroughly drenched and then continually and vigorously fanned by poor policy choices. In other words, the war was caused not by impersonal forces, but by bad decisions in difficult circumstances.

That is the danger that Trump confronts with China today. He must worry about a China that is simultaneously too weak and too strong. To achieve his objectives, he must avoid the Kindleberger trap as well as the Thucydides trap. But, above all, he must avoid the miscalculations, misperceptions, and rash judgments that plague human history.

The age of Trump

On 20 January 2017, Donald Trump will be inaugurated as the 45th President of the United States. I would hate to say ‘I told you so,’ but his election should not have come as a surprise. As I explained in my 2002 book Globalization and its Discontents, the policies we have used to manage globalisation have sown the seeds of widespread disaffection. Ironically, a candidate from the same party that has pushed the hardest for international financial and trade integration won by promising to undo both.

Of course, there is no going back. China and India are now integrated into the global economy, and technological innovation is reducing the number of manufacturing jobs worldwide. Trump cannot recreate the well-paying manufacturing jobs of past decades; he can only push for advanced manufacturing, which requires higher skill sets and employs fewer people.

Rising inequality, meanwhile, will continue to contribute to widespread despair, especially among the white voters in Middle America who handed Trump his victory. As the economists Anne Case and Angus Deaton showed in their study published in December 2015, life expectancy among middle-age white Americans is declining, as rates of suicides, drug use, and alcoholism increase. A year later, the National Center for Health Statistics reported that life expectancy for the country as a whole has declined for the first time in more than 20 years.

In the first three years of the so-called recovery after the 2008 financial crisis, 91% of the gains went to the top 1% of earners. While Wall Street banks were bailed out with billions of dollars in taxpayer money, homeowners received only a pittance. US President Barack Obama saved not only the banks, but also the bankers, shareholders, and bondholders. His economic-policy team of Wall Street insiders broke the rules of capitalism to save the elite, confirming millions of Americans’ suspicion that the system is, as Trump would say, ‘rigged.’

Obama brought ‘change you can believe in’ on certain issues, such as climate policy; but with respect to the economy, he bolstered the status quo—the 30-year experiment with neoliberalism, which promised that the benefits of globalization and liberalisation would ‘trickle down’ to everyone. Instead, the benefits trickled up, partly owing to a political system that now seems to be based on the principle of ‘one dollar, one vote,’ rather than ‘one person, one vote.’

Rising inequality, an unfair political system, and a government that spoke as if it was working for the people while acting for the elites created ideal conditions for a candidate like Trump to exploit. Though wealthy, Trump is clearly not a member of the traditional elite, which lent credence to his promise of ‘real’ change. And yet it will be business as usual under Trump, who will adhere to Republican orthodoxy on taxation and, by appointing lobbyists and industry insiders to his administration, has already broken his promise to ‘drain the swamp’ in Washington, DC.

The rest of Trump’s economic agenda will depend largely on whether House Speaker Paul Ryan is a true fiscal conservative. Trump has proposed that large tax cuts for the rich be combined with massive infrastructure-spending programs, which would boost GDP and improve the government’s fiscal position somewhat, but not nearly as much as advocates of supply-side economics hope. If Ryan is not as concerned about the deficit as he says he is, he will rubberstamp Trump’s agenda, and the economy will receive the Keynesian fiscal stimulus that it has long needed.

Another uncertainty relates to monetary policy. Trump has already spoken out against low interest rates, and there are two vacancies on the US Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors. Add to that the large numbers of Fed officials itching normalise rates, and it is fair bet that they will do so—perhaps more than offsetting Trump’s Keynesian stimulus.

Trump’s pro-growth policies will also be undermined if he exacerbates inequality through his tax proposals, starts a trade war, or abandons America’s commitments to reduce greenhouse-gas emissions (especially if others retaliate with a cross-border tax). Now that Republicans control the White House and both houses of Congress, they will be relatively free to weaken workers’ bargaining power, deregulate Wall Street and other industries, and turn a blind eye to existing antitrust laws—all of which will create more inequality.

If Trump follows through on his campaign threat to impose tariffs on Chinese imports, America’s economy would probably suffer more damage than China’s. Under the existing World Trade Organization framework, for every ‘illegal’ tariff that the US imposes, China can retaliate anywhere it chooses, such as by using trade restrictions to target jobs in the congressional districts of those who support US tariffs.

To be sure, measures against China permitted under the WTO framework, such as anti-dumping tariffs, may be justified in some areas. But Trump has enunciated no guiding principles for trade policy, and the US—which directly subsidises its automobile and aircraft industries, and indirectly subsidises its banks through ultra-low interest rates—would be throwing stones from a glass house. And once this tit-for-tat game begins, it could very well end in the destruction of the open international order created since World War II.

Similarly, the international rule of law, which is enforced primarily through economic sanctions, could fare poorly under Trump. How will the new president respond if Russian-aligned troops escalate the conflict in Eastern Ukraine? America’s real power has always derived from its standing as an inclusive democracy. But people around the world have now lost confidence in democratic processes. Indeed, throughout Africa, I have heard remarks such as, ‘Trump makes our dictators look good.’ As American soft power continues to erode in 2017 and beyond, the future of the international order will become more uncertain.

Meanwhile, the Democratic Party will surely be conducting an election post mortem. Hillary Clinton undeniably lost because she failed to offer voters a convincing vision that was markedly different from the neoliberal agenda that Bill Clinton embraced in the 1990s. Having pursued a political strategy of ‘triangulation’—adopting versions of its opponents’ policies—for more than a generation, the party of the left could no longer present itself as a credible alternative to the party of the right.

The Democrats will have a future only if they reject neoliberalism, and adopt the progressive policies proposed by leaders such as Elizabeth Warren, Bernie Sanders, and Sherrod Brown. This will put them in a strong position against the Republicans, who will have to figure out how to manage a coalition of evangelical Christians, corporate executives, nativists, populists, and isolationists.

With the arrival of Trump, and with both major parties now redefining themselves, the coming year may well be remembered as a turning point in US and world history.

Nulka: the future of Australia’s defence industry

HMAS Perth launches the Nulka missile decoy system during the surface-to-air missile exercise (SAMEX) during Exericise Rim of the Pacific (EX RIMPAC 12). Mid Caption: During Exercise RIMPAC 12, HMAS Perth conducted a surface-to-air missile exercise (SAMEX) about 40 miles off the island of Kauai in the Pacific Missile Range Facility in Hawaii. HMAS Perth used the recently installed phased array missile defence radar to launch two evolved sea sparrow surface to air missiles (ESSM) to hit targets launched from Kauai Island during the missile firing exercise. **Extracted from Video**

I was permitted a point of pride late last year when reports came in that Australia’s decoy rocket, Nulka, diverted a missile attack on the American warship USS Mason off the coast of Yemen. As always, success has a hundred fathers, and credit for the failed missile attack is also being claimed for a couple of fired SM-2s and an evolved Seasparrow. An investigation is underway. The defence industry minister, Christopher Pyne, has no doubt about Australia’s singular role, observing in London recently: ‘A US warship, the USS Mason, was recently attacked while off the coast of Yemen by Houthi rebels with what was believed to be land‑based anti‑ship cruise missiles. Fortunately, the ship was equipped with Australian-made Nulka decoys which were deployed, and the missiles crashed into the sea.’

Nulka is cutting-edge technology and our largest defence export. It’s a product of an exchange I had with the then US Defense Secretary Cap Weinberger in the mid-1980s. Some of it’s told in the Defence Department’s bookNulka: a compelling story—ingenuity, partnership, perseverance. At the time, I was annoyed by our inability to get the codes for the APG 65 radar on the RAAF’s F-18s. The codes supplied to us could only identify Warsaw Pact aircraft as foes when most of our potential targets were Western-sourced. Further, we were then the second largest arms customer for the US defence industry, with nothing to show on the other side of the ledger.

Before the meeting, the department gave me an extensive briefing paper requesting I sign off the termination of then developmental Project Winnin (now Nulka). I didn’t sign it but it was in my notes carried into the meeting. I started with my whinges. Weinberger interrupted me and said, ‘I am sick of your whining but you never give me something concrete.’ I thought he needed an answer and, as luck would have it, one was to hand. I dragged out the briefing paper and replied, ‘How about this then?’ His advisers were aware of the planned cancellation and showed visible consternation. ‘Done’, he immediately responded. He turned to his alarmed folk and said, ‘Make it happen—no argument.’

Later, at the inaugural meeting of AUSMIN in San Francisco in August 1986, we signed off on an agreement to collaborate on full-scale development of the concept developed by our then Defence Science and Technology Organisation. As well as being in service on our warships, the Nulka system is now deployed on many American vessels and, after the Mason incident, I suspect it’ll appear on more.

At the time, and at that stage of development, Nulka was more symbolic. A lot of work had to be done, particularly on the payload, and largely at the American end. The challenge was to produce a signature more powerful for the homing system of an incoming missile than that registered by the ship which launched it. Nulka became an important symbol for both Australian defence science and Australian defence industry. It was important, too, for the alliance as a two-way street. For me, it assuaged some of the sorrow at the removal of New Zealand from the process of the annual meetings.

It’s now a symbol of something else entirely: the possibilities for advanced Australian manufacturing. Protectionism’s back on the table but our protected industries are either gone or their remaining elements, globally competitive. A protected market of 24 million sitting in a regional market of 3 billion makes no sense for an investor anymore. That horse has bolted, and the gate can’t sensibly be closed.

Our manufacturing future lies in niche products, internationally collaborative enterprises and global supply chains. Nulka ticks all these boxes. As a BAE Systems Australia publication points out, it’s the prime contractor and systems design agent. Lockheed Martin (USA) is the design agent for the electronic warfare payload. Aerojet Inc. (USA) manufactures the rocket motor. BAE Systems builds the flight control hardware in Edinburgh Parks, South Australia, and tests and assembles the system at its Nulka Round Assembly Facility in Mulwala, New South Wales. These are a powerful group of defence manufacturers. As well as being our largest regular defence export program, Nulka is subject to continual development to keep it ahead of emerging countermeasures.

The Nulka story is part of the ballast of our alliance relationship as we seek to influence the direction of president-elect Donald Trump’s policy in our region in particular. The Nulka system will be part of the defences of the new warships ships he plans to construct.

Now’s not an easy time. Our region will want us to spend a great deal of our political capital trying to alter what’s an obvious predilection on the part of the incoming Trump administration to nationalist unilateralism—a direction which may destabilise hopes for peace and prosperity. Six years ago we spent some of that capital influencing the Obama administration, classic American liberal internationalists, to extend that approach to the Asian pivot. They fitted in well, ticking all the boxes Asians demand of their international community—basically, being there and engaging. That’s going to be a lot harder after 20 January.